Sunday, September 28, 2014

THE ROLE LATE BABA WA TAIFA.. in rising tanzanian both economy and social development

He spearheaded our freedom, he established republic in 1962, he established monoparty in 1965,in 1967 he adopted UJAMAA policy which aimed at drawing self sufficient economy with industrial establishment such as Mwatex,Sungura tex, Kilitex,Mutex and Urafiki x...these all enabled high export of industrial manufactired such as kanga,tshirts,shorts,cashewnuts, etc for this matter tanzanian currency. Became more valuable to Us doller..eg 7tz sh = 1$ doller.. still nyerere established ujamaa village for urbanisation of tanzania. He discouraged tribalism, he eradicated religous intellerance,he encouraged patriotism and strong nationalism,he discouraged individualism and egocentric, he cursed against poverty and ignarance by making free education to every tanzanian civilian..eg UPE... l was to rise tanzania into top ten developed powers.. but his dreamz was in general encountered by the collapse of our aids and friend financial provider that was USSR..in 1980s which followed with SAPs.
This marked the climax of BABA WaTAIFA to make tanzania developed state.. we all say Thank you Mw. Nyerere.. i sincerly adhere your advice .. i hope one day i will be like you ameeeeeeen... God bless Tanzania God bless africa..

Monday, July 28, 2014

See young palastinian under persecution...

  You innocent palastian suffering from persecution... Of israel... God help and rescue them from persecution of zionism type Ameen...

Thursday, July 24, 2014

Western mass media tend to be bias on exposing the middle east crisis...

CNN and BBC.. are said to expose the griverances of israel and hide the cries of palestinians. Several kills done by israel to palestinians involve about 400 people in Gaza are not advertized by western media indeed... But a single kill of jewish citizen is exporsed by CNN and BBC all over the world.. is it freedom of mass media???? World see these an imperialistic mass media who work for capitalists gains... I curse this in the name of God creator...

Human rights is for allied power and jews not for black people and palestinians...

Where is AMNEST international in Gaza???? Where is UNO in Gaza???? Where is human rights in GazA???  Where is holly land in Gaza???? Arab league is now terminated by USA.. except iran...only...that remained who still fighting for palestinians rights.... We will never forget you YASSIR ARAFAt... With your INTIFFADDA... Movement.... RIP.... Arafat....

Dear world see how holly people preach a word of God.. in Gaza...

Israel has killed mass number of young palestinians... RIP... Curse be upon zionist jews...

Innocent palestinian child throws the stone over zionist tank run by israelite terrorists...

See young palestinian angainst persecution of israelite zionist tank running to destroy innocent palestinians at Gaza strip... God rescue them from persecution... And zionists terrorism.... Up now since last about 539 palestinians reported to be killed by israel attack..over gaza...

Terribly road accident kills one pedestrian..

Pedestrian dies of road accident in tanzania ... Type RIP....

Wednesday, July 23, 2014

USA feels xorry for Boers plain incident of malaysia but USA pretends blind to palestinian deceased made israels is human rights...??

Usa and allied powers may you feel grief to innocent palestinians at Gaza strip who are killed by jews... Their number are greater than those of holland- malayisian plain... God bless palestinians at Gaza rescue them from zionists terrorism....

Tuesday, July 22, 2014

Mansa khankhan mussa the successor of mansa sundiatha keitha.. was the leading gold owner king in the western sudanic state ( maghreb state)

Mansa mussa was the king of mali empire who owned gold wealthy and  made mali to be dynasty with islamic laws... His empire was defeated by sun Ally in 1464 under mansa uli... Which marked the rise of songhai... Empire...

ISRAEL STOP TO KILL PALESTIANS

God help palestinian children at GAZA STRIP... From persecution and slaughter..... Type AMEN....

World! see how israel kills innocent palestinians

About
300 palestinians have been killed at Gaza strip...since two weeks ago.. God help these young generation innocents who suffer with no reason. TYPE AMEN.....

Tuesday, April 22, 2014

Home | Other Papers and Essays Explanations of Japan’s Imperialistic Expansion, 1894-1910 Bill Gordon December 2003 Japan emerged in 1853 from two and a half centuries of self-imposed peaceful isolation, but within a few decades the country’s leaders embarked on a policy of aggressive territorial expansion.  During the last half of the nineteenth century, the Western imperialist powers of England, France, and Germany established the model for acquisition of colonies in Asia and for the partition of China into spheres of influence.  Near the end of the century, about the same time Japan began to capture colonial territory, the United States and Russia also initiated their imperialistic expansion in Asia. This paper will examine four of the most influential theories of imperialism to determine whether they can provide explanations for Japan’s imperialism from 1894 to 1910, when Japan formally annexed Korea.  The four theories to be reviewed will be Hobson's theory of domestic market underconsumption that leads to capitalists seeking profits overseas, Lenin's theory of the monopoly stage of capitalism, Schumpeter's theory of inherited warlike tendencies from prior generations, and nationalism's focus on politics as the critical factor.  Although other theories of imperialism exist, these four theories cover a broad range of economic, political, and sociological factors that could explain Japan’s imperialistic expansion.  This essay's review of Japan's history of imperialism from 1894 to 1910 will show that the theory of nationalism provides the best explanations of the causes of Japan's militaristic actions and colonial acquisitions, although Schumpeter's sociological-based theory seems to provide some explanation for the actions of the Meiji Period (1868-1912) leaders. Section 1 of this essay reviews the key points of the four theories of imperialism.  The following section examines some highlights of Japan's history of imperialism between 1894 and 1910.  Section 3 evaluates each theory as to whether or not it explains Japan's imperialistic actions during this time period.  The final section provides conclusions. 1. Theories of Imperialism Imperialism can be defined as direct or indirect domination of an industrialized country over a colonial territory or another country.  Although the theories of Hobson, Lenin, and Schumpeter generally focus on imperialism of European powers, especially Great Britain, in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, this paper will examine these theories to assess their relevance in explaining the causes of Japan’s imperialist push into other countries of Asia.  These three theories and the theory of nationalism have been subjected to various criticisms, but proponents still exist for each one.  For example, Nowell (2000) argues for the historical validity and contemporary relevance of Hobson's theory.  Schumpeter's "idea still has a large following" (Howard and King 2000, 19), and there have always been numerous supporters for Lenin's theory and the nationalist theory.  J.A. Hobson ([1905] 1938, 80-81) identified the taproot of imperialism to be surplus capital in the home country in search of profitable investments in foreign markets.  The profits earned by the small number of rich capitalists in the home market resulted in chronic oversaving, since they had a lower marginal propensity to consume than poor workers with wages based upon the cost of living rather than the efficiency of their labor (83-84).  Although imperialism does not make sense as a business policy for a nation as a whole due to its enormous military and administrative expense, "strong organized industrial and financial interests" that stand to gain from imperialism find ways to put this expense on the general public (46, 106).  Hobson argued that if purchasing power were reapportioned from the rich to the poor, then the home market would provide full employment of capital and labor with no overproduction, and there would be no need for the imperialistic fight for foreign markets (86-87). Lenin ([1917] 1939, 14, 88) expressed the Marxist view of imperialism as the "monopoly stage of capitalism," the highest and final stage of capitalism prior to the proletarian social revolution.  Essential features of imperialism include the concentration of production and capital into monopolies (large-scale firms), the merging of bank and industrial capital, the export of capital, the apportionment of the world among the large-scale firms, and the division of territories of the world among the great capitalist powers (89).  Lenin also emphasized that the need for raw materials drove capitalists to acquire colonies (82-84).  Like Hobson, Lenin argues that surplus capital will be exported abroad for the purpose of increasing profits (63).  However, in contrast to Hobson's view that the problem of surplus capital could be resolved by redistribution of purchasing power within the home country, Lenin believed that the wretched condition of the masses was inevitable and that imperialistic expansion by capitalist countries could not be avoided. Joseph Schumpeter ([1919] 1951, 6) considered imperialism to be "the objectless disposition on the part of the state to unlimited forcible expansion."  Although Schumpeter does not specifically address Japanese imperialism, he provides a wide range of historical examples to show that nations and classes seek expansion only for the sake of expanding and dominion only for the sake of ruling.  The bellicosity of an autocratic state derives from "the necessities of its social structure, from the inherited dispositions of its ruling class, rather than from the immediate advantages to be derived from the conquest" (59).  As a country becomes more capitalistic, the energy for war decreases as the "competitive system absorbs the full energies of most of the people at all economic levels" (69).  Schumpeter viewed imperialism as an atavism in the social structure of capitalist states, an element from prior history that affects emotional reactions (65). Nationalism as a theory of imperialism goes under several other names, such as "power politics" (Cohen 1973, 231; Mommsen 1980, 74) and "mercantilism" (Brown 1974, 26; Gilpin 1975, 27).  The theory of nationalism emphasizes the essential role of the state in imperialistic behavior as a nation seeks to maximize its power, prestige, and wealth relative to other countries.  Nationalists consider economic relations between nations to be conflictual, a zero-sum game where the gain of one nation is the loss of another nation.  This theory views capitalists as willing to invest wherever profits are expected to be greatest, either in the home country, overseas colonies, or other countries, so sometimes the interests of state leaders and business capitalists may coincide in plans for imperialist expansion.  However, according to nationalism, ultimately politics determines economic relations and organization.  Nationalists stress national security and national sentiment in international political and economic dynamics (Gilpin 1975, 31). 2. Japan Joins the Imperialist Club Japan forcefully acquired three major foreign territories between 1894 and 1910: Taiwan in 1895 after the Sino-Japanese War of 1894-5; Korea as a protectorate in 1905 after the Russo-Japanese War of 1904-5, then as a colony when unilaterally annexed by Japan in 1910; and the Kwantung Leased Territories in 1905 in southern Manchuria when Japan succeeded to Russia's leases after the Russo-Japanese War.  This section of the essay summarizes briefly the imperialistic expansion of Japan during the period and the actions of the world's imperialist powers that influenced the course of Japan's actions. Korea occupied a strategically important geographic position just to the west of the southern part of Japan.  For the two decades prior to the start of the Sino-Japanese War of 1894-5, China and Japan quarreled over Korea's internal politics and Chinese influence in the country's government.  Japan went to war with China over proposed administrative and financial reforms in Korea.  As a result of the treaty after the Japanese victory, China recognized Korea's independence.  Japan also received a large indemnity; acquired Taiwan and the Liaodong Peninsula in southern Manchuria; and obtained several other concessions from China. Soon after Japan and China signed the treaty to conclude the Sino-Japanese War, the Western imperialist powers made the first of several moves that would influence significantly Japan's ideas about future imperialistic expansion.  Japan observed the Western powers' intense rivalries and imperialistic acquisitions.  Only six days after signing the treaty, Germany, Russia, and France forced Japan to surrender its claims on the Liaodong Peninsula, which became a bitter diplomatic defeat for Japan.  In 1898, only three years later, Russia pushed into Manchuria and obtained a leasehold from China for the same peninsula Japan had been forced to relinquish.  During the same year, the United States, which embarked on its overseas imperialistic expansion about the same time as Japan, annexed Hawaii and the Philippines.  From 1895 to 1900, the imperialist powers of France, Germany, Russia, and England divided up China into spheres of influence, which included special railway and mining concessions, leased territory, and promises from China that comparable privileges would not be granted to other countries in a specified area.  Between 1900 and 1905, Japan became a full-fledged member in the club of imperialist powers.  In 1900, Japan showed its military prowess when 8,000 of its troops joined 9,000 soldiers from the Western powers to fight side by side to defeat the Boxer Rebellion in China.  In 1902, Japan and Great Britain signed a mutual defense alliance, a document that in effect recognized Japan as one of the world's great powers.  In 1904 and 1905, Japan and Russia went to war over their territorial and political disputes in Korea and southern Manchuria.  After the destruction of the Russian fleet, Japan emerged from the Russo-Japanese War as one of the world's great military and political powers.  The Portsmouth Treaty to end the war gave Japan control of Korea and the Kwantung Leased Territories.  Japan stood as one of the world's powers with a colonial empire of its own.  3. Explanations of Japan’s Early Imperialism This section assesses the four theories of imperialism to determine whether they help to explain Japanese imperialistic expansion between 1894 and 1910.  A. Hobson’s Theory The core of Hobson’s theory is the existence of excess capital seeking profits overseas.  However, during this period Japan had no excess capital and had to borrow large amounts from Britain and the United States to finance its rapid industrial expansion and its wars with China and Russia.  Japan's outstanding foreign loan indebtedness grew steadily, starting from near zero in 1896, to 421 million yen in 1904, and then to 1,970 million yen in 1913 (Lockwood 1954, 254-255).  Foreign holdings of government bonds comprised over 60% of Japan's national debt of 2,600 million yen in 1913 (256). Hobson's theory does not hold up as an explanation for Japan's early imperialism because of the relative unimportance of the financial transactions between the home country and its colonies.  Although imports from the colonies as a share of total trade with other countries increased from 1.7% in 1894-1903 to 6.9% in 1904-1914 and exports to the colonies increased from 2.7% of total trade in 1894-1903 to 7.8% in 1904-1913 (Cohen 1973, 62), the levels remained very low.  Foreign trade made up about one quarter of Japan's economic activity from 1904 to 1913 (Crawcour 1997, 78), so trade with the colonies accounted for less than 2% of Japan's total economic activity during this period. B. Lenin’s Theory Lenin advocated a theory of monopoly capital where capitalists wanted to employ surplus capital abroad to achieve higher profits than the domestic market.  As explained in the previous section, Japan had loans from foreign countries and a relatively low level of economic activity with the colonies during the period of Japan's first imperialistic acquisitions.  Most of the funds from foreign debt went for military expenditures, and only 3% of the funds went to development of Japan's colonies (Lockwood 1954, 35). Lenin considered the existence of large-scale firms with great economic power (monopolists) and the merging of bank and industrial capital to be key characteristics of imperialism.  In Japan between 1894 and 1910, a handful of huge privately-owned conglomerates called zaibatsu increased their economic power.  Although some of the zaibatsu such as Mitsui and Sumitomo had histories of more than 200 years, they strengthened their economic position as the government, starting in the early 1880s, sold to them several industrial plants and mines that become very profitable.  Each zaibatsu also owned a bank, but the five largest banks' share of loans was only 17% of the total market by 1910 (Nakamura [1971] 1983, 207), so this low figure provides little support for Lenin's assertion of finance capital monopolies being an essential feature of imperialism.  Likewise, the economic power of the zaibatsu companies from 1894 to 1910 did not approach anywhere near their domination just prior to and during World War II.  Although Japan had made rapid progress in industrialization and modernization up to 1910, it could still be considered a developing country.  Agriculture, forestry, and fisheries accounted for 33% of economic output and 67% of employment in 1910.  Manufacturing and construction contributed only 23% to economic output, and over half of manufacturing production came from cottage industries employing less than five people.  Manufacturing consisted mainly of food products and textiles at 34% each, whereas heavy industry made up only 21% (21-23, 80). In addition to surplus capital in search of higher profits overseas, Lenin stressed the acquisition of raw materials as a major reason for capitalists to acquire colonies.  Very little evidence exists to support that Japan acquired its colonies between 1894 and 1910 for raw materials.  Korea and Taiwan had no significant known mineral resources except for a small amount of iron ore in Korea, so the only substantial natural resources were agricultural products, mainly rice but also sugarcane in Taiwan.  Although Korea and Taiwan provided rice to Japan, especially in poor harvest years, only 18% of Japan's annual rice imports came from these two colonies from 1905 to 1910 (Duus 1984, 171).  After acquiring Taiwan as a colony in 1895, Japan encouraged the planting of sugarcane to supply domestic needs.  However, Taiwanese land devoted to sugarcane production from 1901 to 1910 was only 7% of the amount of land devoted to rice (Beasley 1987, 150), and Japan imposed a high tariff on sugar imports from countries other than Taiwan, so Japanese consumers suffered from higher prices.  The Kwantung Leased Territories had few natural resources, but they did help serve as a foothold to facilitate the development and extraction of Manchuria's natural resources (Ho 1984, 350). Lenin's theory does not help explain Japan's imperialism from 1894 to 1910 due to the nonexistence of capital surpluses, the low level of economic activity with the colonies, the lack of dominance of the zaibatsu, and the low levels of the colonies' raw materials. C. Schumpeter’s Theory Schumpeter believed that imperialism represented the survival of older social structures, such as a warrior class, within a capitalist economy.  This theory seems to partially explain the attitudes of Japan's leaders toward imperialistic expansion.  Japan had a feudalistic social structure with a warrior class (samurai) until the downfall of the Shogunate in 1868 and the implementation of numerous reforms over the next five years under the new Meiji government.  Members of the former military aristocracy took leadership positions in the new government, and the military bent of some of these leaders became quickly evident, as they strongly pressed for military action in the early 1870s to conquer Korea.  A majority of the country's leaders decided to postpone this military action to concentrate on modernization and industrialization, but even the leaders who recommended not to go to war did not necessarily oppose the action in theory, only that the timing should wait until Japan became stronger industrially and militarily. Although some authors contend that Japan's imperialistic spirit dated back to before the beginning of the start of the Tokugawa Period in 1600, they provide little evidence as to why such a militaristic attitude would remain entrenched in a people living in a country where peace reigned for about two and half centuries under the Tokugawa Shogunate (1600-1868).  Boulding and Gleason (1972, 241-242) argue that Japan's imperialistic expansion was a continuation from several centuries before: "Even before 1600, . . . colonies were established in areas of Southeast Asia, and in 1592 Korea was invaded in an extraordinary, but abortive, attempt to conquer China. . . . But the Meiji government, once isolationism had been abandoned, resumed the imperialistic practices of the earlier era."  Lockwood (1954, 7) argues that the coming of Westerners in the last half of the nineteenth century "revived and intensified memories of European ambitions and predatory rivalries dating back to the sixteenth century."  Although some leaders in the Meiji Era tried to revive memories of historical events for their own propaganda purposes, little evidence exists that such militaristic attitudes and memories of Western aggression continued in the Japanese people during a period of peace lasting over 200 years. Schumpeter argued that capitalists have no economic incentives for imperialism, and Hobson also considered that imperialism is not profitable for a nation due its huge military and administrative costs.  The evidence in Japan's case supports Schumpeter and Hobson since the colonies did not provide profits for the country as a whole.  Lockwood (1954, 52) summarizes the effects of Japan's early imperialism: But it is certain that colonial enterprise occupied a subordinate place in Japanese economic development during the first three decades of the twentieth century.  And it is likely that whatever contributions were made to Japan's national income and industrial development by political control over these areas were more than offset, even at the time, by the costs of the military outlays, developmental subsidies, and tariff preferences through which she acquired and developed her empire. Duus (1984, 147) points out that business leaders during the period of Japan's early imperialistic expansion had much more interest in China, with a "vast population, size, and well-developed commercial economy" that "made its market larger, more penetrable, and more easily exploited than those of Taiwan or Korea." Schumpeter's theory provides some insights into the reasons for Japan's imperialism from 1894 to 1910, but it fails to explain how Japan suddenly became an aggressive conqueror of foreign territories after over two centuries of self-imposed peaceful isolation. D. Nationalism The theory of nationalism provides the best explanations for Japan's imperialistic actions between 1894 and 1905.  The following points support nationalism as the best theory to understand Japan's wars and colonial acquisitions: (1) Japan's deep concerns for national security, (2) its emulation of the imperialistic behaviors of Western powers, and (3) Japanese national ideals and personal characteristics. The United States forcibly opened Japan to the outside world in 1853.  Soon thereafter, Japan was pressured by the imperialist powers to sign "unequal treaties," which granted foreigners in Japan extraterritoriality in legal cases and which imposed on Japan low tariff rates for which the imperialist countries did not grant corresponding concessions in their rates.  The leaders of the Meiji government, formed in 1868 after the downfall of the Tokugawa Shogunate, considered national security and defense to be the top priority in order to prevent subjugation by the Western powers.  The nationalistic policy of fukoku kyōhei (rich country, strong military) emphasized Japan's goals to develop the country economically to catch up with the Western powers and to increase its military strength to ensure its existence as an independent country.  Japan fought the later wars against China and Russia in 1894-5 and 1904-5, respectively, to ensure that Korea would not be used by another imperialist power to threaten Japan's security. Japan emulated the imperialistic behaviors of the Western powers.  From the beginning of the Meiji Period in 1868, Japan's leaders sought to make the country an industrial and military power on par with the Western imperialist powers.  When Japan emerged from its isolation and took steps to industrialize and modernize, the international environment was one of intense competition between powers that tried to maximize their political and economic positions relative to other powers and less developed countries.  Overseas colonies provided the imperialist powers with prestige and status, so Japan's leaders naturally celebrated when its empire expanded to include Taiwan, Korea, and the Kwantung Leased Territories. The Western concept of Social Darwinism, with the ultimate domination of the world by the strongest nations, fit well with belief of many Japanese that they were the chosen people of Asia and a divinely favored race.  Yukichi Fukuzawa, one of Japan's educational leaders and founder of one of Japan's most influential newspapers, expressed Japan's early imperialistic desires in 1882, "We shall someday raise the national power of Japan so that not only shall we control the natives of China and India as the English do today, but we shall also possess in our hands the power to rebuke the English and to rule Asia ourselves" (Nester 1996, 63).  The Japanese people also had certain personal characteristics that supported the country's rapid economic growth and imperialistic expansion.  Allen (1981, 15) explains, "Throughout their history they have shown a gift for rapidly assimilating new ideas and practices, a boldness in executing large projects and, above all, a trained and frequently exercised capacity for organization." 4. Conclusion The theories of Hobson and Lenin provide little insight into the reasons for Japan's imperialist expansion between 1894 and 1910 since the economic conditions they considered to be the causes for imperialism did not exist in Japan at the time.  Schumpeter's theory of imperialism has some relevance to Japan's case, since the leaders who promoted Japan's wars in the Meiji Period came from the former samurai class.  However, this theory does not fully explain Japan's imperialistic actions since the samurai did not fight for over two centuries during the self-imposed peaceful isolation of the Tokugawa Period. Japan's concerns for national security, its emulation of Western powers in their imperialistic expansion, and Japanese national ideals supporting overseas expansion lead to the conclusion that nationalism provides the best explanation of Japan's imperialistic expansion in comparison to the other three theories of imperialism.  Although the theory of nationalism sheds the most light on Japan's imperialism from 1894 to 1905, this does not mean that Japan's aggression and colonial expansion represented the best course of action.  Kōtoku Shūsui, a Socialist leader in Japan, vividly described in 1901 imperialism's serious drawbacks (Iriye 1972, 75): Imperialists in Japan and elsewhere are like drunken men, intoxicated by patriotism and militarism, which are nothing but expressions of their animal instincts.  They bleed people white with taxes, expand armaments, divert productive capital for unproductive ends, cause prices to rise, and invite excessive imports.  These are all for the sake of the state.  Government, education, commerce, and industry are sacrificed to patriotism, which is the root of militarism and imperialism.  Bibliography Allen, G.C.  1981.  A Short Economic History of Modern Japan.  Fourth edition.  New York: St. Martin's Press. Beasley, W.G. 1987.  Japanese Imperialism 1894-1945.  Oxford: Clarendon Press. Boulding, Kenneth E. and Alan H. Gleason.  1972.  "War as an Investment: The Strange Case of Japan."  In Kenneth E. Boulding and Tapan Mukerjee, eds., Economic Imperialism: A Book of Readings, pp. 240-261.  Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Brown, Michael Barratt.  1974.  The Economics of Imperialism.  Harmondsworth: Penguin Books. Cohen, Benjamin J.  1973.  The Question of Imperialism: The Political Economy of Dominance and Dependence.  New York: Basic Books. Crawcour, E. Sydney.  1997.  "Industrialization and technological change, 1885-1920."  In Kozo Yamamura, ed., The Economic Emergence of Modern Japan, pp. 50-115.  Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Duus, Peter.  1984.  "Economic Dimensions of Meiji Imperialism: The Case of Korea, 1895-1910."  In Myers, Ramon H. and Mark R. Peattie, eds., The Japanese Colonial Empire, 1895-1945, pp. 128-171.  Princeton: Princeton University Press. Gilpin, Robert.  1975.  U.S. Power and the Multinational Corporation: The Political Economy of Foreign Direct Investment.  New York: Basic Books. Ho, Samuel Pao-San.  1984.  "Colonialism and Development: Korea, Taiwan, and Kwantung."  In Myers, Ramon H. and Mark R. Peattie, eds., The Japanese Colonial Empire, 1895-1945, pp. 347-398.  Princeton: Princeton University Press. Hobson, J.A.  [1905] 1938.  Imperialism: A Study.  Reprint, with an introduction by Philip Siegelman, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Howard, M.C. and J.E. King.  2000.  "Whatever Happened to Imperialism?"  In Chilcote, Ronald H., The Political Economy of Imperialism: Critical Appraisals, pp. 19-40.  Lanham, Maryland: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers. Iriye, Akira.  1972.  Pacific Estrangement: Japanese and American Expansion, 1897-1911.  Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Lenin, V.I.  [1917] 1939.  Imperialism: The Highest Stage of Capitalism.  New York: International Publishers. Lockwood, William W.  1954.  The Economic Development of Japan: Growth and Structural Change, 1868-1938.  Princeton: Princeton University Press. Mommsen, Wolfgang J.  1980.  Theories of Imperialism.  Translated by P.S. Falla.  New York: Random House. Nakamura, Takafusa.  [1971] 1983.  Economic Growth in Prewar Japan.  Translated by Robert A. Feldman.  New Haven: Yale University Press. Nester, William R.  1996.  Power across the Pacific: A Diplomatic History of American Relations with Japan.  New York: New York University Press. Nowell, Gregory P.  2000. "Hobson's Imperialism: Its Historical Validity and Contemporary Relevance."  In Chilcote, Ronald H., The Political Economy of Imperialism: Critical Appraisals, pp. 85-109.  Lanham, Maryland: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers. Schumpeter, Joseph.  [1919] 1951.  "The Sociology of Imperialism."  In Imperialism and Social Classes, pp. 1-98.  New York: Meridian Books. Home | Top | Other Papers and Essays | About the Author

Home | Other Papers and Essays Explanations of Japan’s Imperialistic Expansion, 1894-1910  Bill Gordon December 2003  Japan emerged in 1853 from two and a half centuries of self-imposed peaceful isolation, but within a few decades the country’s leaders embarked on a policy of aggressive territorial expansion.  During the last half of the nineteenth century, the Western imperialist powers of England, France, and Germany established the model for acquisition of colonies in Asia and for the partition of China into spheres of influence.  Near the end of the century, about the same time Japan began to capture colonial territory, the United States and Russia also initiated their imperialistic expansion in Asia. This paper will examine four of the most influential theories of imperialism to determine whether they can provide explanations for Japan’s imperialism from 1894 to 1910, when Japan formally annexed Korea.  The four theories to be reviewed will be Hobson's theory of domestic market underconsumption that leads to capitalists seeking profits overseas, Lenin's theory of the monopoly stage of capitalism, Schumpeter's theory of inherited warlike tendencies from prior generations, and nationalism's focus on politics as the critical factor.  Although other theories of imperialism exist, these four theories cover a broad range of economic, political, and sociological factors that could explain Japan’s imperialistic expansion.  This essay's review of Japan's history of imperialism from 1894 to 1910 will show that the theory of nationalism provides the best explanations of the causes of Japan's militaristic actions and colonial acquisitions, although Schumpeter's sociological-based theory seems to provide some explanation for the actions of the Meiji Period (1868-1912) leaders.  Section 1 of this essay reviews the key points of the four theories of imperialism.  The following section examines some highlights of Japan's history of imperialism between 1894 and 1910.  Section 3 evaluates each theory as to whether or not it explains Japan's imperialistic actions during this time period.  The final section provides conclusions.  1. Theories of Imperialism  Imperialism can be defined as direct or indirect domination of an industrialized country over a colonial territory or another country.  Although the theories of Hobson, Lenin, and Schumpeter generally focus on imperialism of European powers, especially Great Britain, in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, this paper will examine these theories to assess their relevance in explaining the causes of Japan’s imperialist push into other countries of Asia.  These three theories and the theory of nationalism have been subjected to various criticisms, but proponents still exist for each one.  For example, Nowell (2000) argues for the historical validity and contemporary relevance of Hobson's theory.  Schumpeter's "idea still has a large following" (Howard and King 2000, 19), and there have always been numerous supporters for Lenin's theory and the nationalist theory.   J.A. Hobson ([1905] 1938, 80-81) identified the taproot of imperialism to be surplus capital in the home country in search of profitable investments in foreign markets.  The profits earned by the small number of rich capitalists in the home market resulted in chronic oversaving, since they had a lower marginal propensity to consume than poor workers with wages based upon the cost of living rather than the efficiency of their labor (83-84).  Although imperialism does not make sense as a business policy for a nation as a whole due to its enormous military and administrative expense, "strong organized industrial and financial interests" that stand to gain from imperialism find ways to put this expense on the general public (46, 106).  Hobson argued that if purchasing power were reapportioned from the rich to the poor, then the home market would provide full employment of capital and labor with no overproduction, and there would be no need for the imperialistic fight for foreign markets (86-87).  Lenin ([1917] 1939, 14, 88) expressed the Marxist view of imperialism as the "monopoly stage of capitalism," the highest and final stage of capitalism prior to the proletarian social revolution.  Essential features of imperialism include the concentration of production and capital into monopolies (large-scale firms), the merging of bank and industrial capital, the export of capital, the apportionment of the world among the large-scale firms, and the division of territories of the world among the great capitalist powers (89).  Lenin also emphasized that the need for raw materials drove capitalists to acquire colonies (82-84).  Like Hobson, Lenin argues that surplus capital will be exported abroad for the purpose of increasing profits (63).  However, in contrast to Hobson's view that the problem of surplus capital could be resolved by redistribution of purchasing power within the home country, Lenin believed that the wretched condition of the masses was inevitable and that imperialistic expansion by capitalist countries could not be avoided.  Joseph Schumpeter ([1919] 1951, 6) considered imperialism to be "the objectless disposition on the part of the state to unlimited forcible expansion."  Although Schumpeter does not specifically address Japanese imperialism, he provides a wide range of historical examples to show that nations and classes seek expansion only for the sake of expanding and dominion only for the sake of ruling.  The bellicosity of an autocratic state derives from "the necessities of its social structure, from the inherited dispositions of its ruling class, rather than from the immediate advantages to be derived from the conquest" (59).  As a country becomes more capitalistic, the energy for war decreases as the "competitive system absorbs the full energies of most of the people at all economic levels" (69).  Schumpeter viewed imperialism as an atavism in the social structure of capitalist states, an element from prior history that affects emotional reactions (65).  Nationalism as a theory of imperialism goes under several other names, such as "power politics" (Cohen 1973, 231; Mommsen 1980, 74) and "mercantilism" (Brown 1974, 26; Gilpin 1975, 27).  The theory of nationalism emphasizes the essential role of the state in imperialistic behavior as a nation seeks to maximize its power, prestige, and wealth relative to other countries.  Nationalists consider economic relations between nations to be conflictual, a zero-sum game where the gain of one nation is the loss of another nation.  This theory views capitalists as willing to invest wherever profits are expected to be greatest, either in the home country, overseas colonies, or other countries, so sometimes the interests of state leaders and business capitalists may coincide in plans for imperialist expansion.  However, according to nationalism, ultimately politics determines economic relations and organization.  Nationalists stress national security and national sentiment in international political and economic dynamics (Gilpin 1975, 31).  2. Japan Joins the Imperialist Club  Japan forcefully acquired three major foreign territories between 1894 and 1910: Taiwan in 1895 after the Sino-Japanese War of 1894-5; Korea as a protectorate in 1905 after the Russo-Japanese War of 1904-5, then as a colony when unilaterally annexed by Japan in 1910; and the Kwantung Leased Territories in 1905 in southern Manchuria when Japan succeeded to Russia's leases after the Russo-Japanese War.  This section of the essay summarizes briefly the imperialistic expansion of Japan during the period and the actions of the world's imperialist powers that influenced the course of Japan's actions.  Korea occupied a strategically important geographic position just to the west of the southern part of Japan.  For the two decades prior to the start of the Sino-Japanese War of 1894-5, China and Japan quarreled over Korea's internal politics and Chinese influence in the country's government.  Japan went to war with China over proposed administrative and financial reforms in Korea.  As a result of the treaty after the Japanese victory, China recognized Korea's independence.  Japan also received a large indemnity; acquired Taiwan and the Liaodong Peninsula in southern Manchuria; and obtained several other concessions from China.  Soon after Japan and China signed the treaty to conclude the Sino-Japanese War, the Western imperialist powers made the first of several moves that would influence significantly Japan's ideas about future imperialistic expansion.  Japan observed the Western powers' intense rivalries and imperialistic acquisitions.  Only six days after signing the treaty, Germany, Russia, and France forced Japan to surrender its claims on the Liaodong Peninsula, which became a bitter diplomatic defeat for Japan.  In 1898, only three years later, Russia pushed into Manchuria and obtained a leasehold from China for the same peninsula Japan had been forced to relinquish.  During the same year, the United States, which embarked on its overseas imperialistic expansion about the same time as Japan, annexed Hawaii and the Philippines.  From 1895 to 1900, the imperialist powers of France, Germany, Russia, and England divided up China into spheres of influence, which included special railway and mining concessions, leased territory, and promises from China that comparable privileges would not be granted to other countries in a specified area.   Between 1900 and 1905, Japan became a full-fledged member in the club of imperialist powers.  In 1900, Japan showed its military prowess when 8,000 of its troops joined 9,000 soldiers from the Western powers to fight side by side to defeat the Boxer Rebellion in China.  In 1902, Japan and Great Britain signed a mutual defense alliance, a document that in effect recognized Japan as one of the world's great powers.  In 1904 and 1905, Japan and Russia went to war over their territorial and political disputes in Korea and southern Manchuria.  After the destruction of the Russian fleet, Japan emerged from the Russo-Japanese War as one of the world's great military and political powers.  The Portsmouth Treaty to end the war gave Japan control of Korea and the Kwantung Leased Territories.  Japan stood as one of the world's powers with a colonial empire of its own.   3. Explanations of Japan’s Early Imperialism  This section assesses the four theories of imperialism to determine whether they help to explain Japanese imperialistic expansion between 1894 and 1910.   A. Hobson’s Theory  The core of Hobson’s theory is the existence of excess capital seeking profits overseas.  However, during this period Japan had no excess capital and had to borrow large amounts from Britain and the United States to finance its rapid industrial expansion and its wars with China and Russia.  Japan's outstanding foreign loan indebtedness grew steadily, starting from near zero in 1896, to 421 million yen in 1904, and then to 1,970 million yen in 1913 (Lockwood 1954, 254-255).  Foreign holdings of government bonds comprised over 60% of Japan's national debt of 2,600 million yen in 1913 (256).  Hobson's theory does not hold up as an explanation for Japan's early imperialism because of the relative unimportance of the financial transactions between the home country and its colonies.  Although imports from the colonies as a share of total trade with other countries increased from 1.7% in 1894-1903 to 6.9% in 1904-1914 and exports to the colonies increased from 2.7% of total trade in 1894-1903 to 7.8% in 1904-1913 (Cohen 1973, 62), the levels remained very low.  Foreign trade made up about one quarter of Japan's economic activity from 1904 to 1913 (Crawcour 1997, 78), so trade with the colonies accounted for less than 2% of Japan's total economic activity during this period.  B. Lenin’s Theory  Lenin advocated a theory of monopoly capital where capitalists wanted to employ surplus capital abroad to achieve higher profits than the domestic market.  As explained in the previous section, Japan had loans from foreign countries and a relatively low level of economic activity with the colonies during the period of Japan's first imperialistic acquisitions.  Most of the funds from foreign debt went for military expenditures, and only 3% of the funds went to development of Japan's colonies (Lockwood 1954, 35).  Lenin considered the existence of large-scale firms with great economic power (monopolists) and the merging of bank and industrial capital to be key characteristics of imperialism.  In Japan between 1894 and 1910, a handful of huge privately-owned conglomerates called zaibatsu increased their economic power.  Although some of the zaibatsu such as Mitsui and Sumitomo had histories of more than 200 years, they strengthened their economic position as the government, starting in the early 1880s, sold to them several industrial plants and mines that become very profitable.  Each zaibatsu also owned a bank, but the five largest banks' share of loans was only 17% of the total market by 1910 (Nakamura [1971] 1983, 207), so this low figure provides little support for Lenin's assertion of finance capital monopolies being an essential feature of imperialism.  Likewise, the economic power of the zaibatsu companies from 1894 to 1910 did not approach anywhere near their domination just prior to and during World War II.  Although Japan had made rapid progress in industrialization and modernization up to 1910, it could still be considered a developing country.  Agriculture, forestry, and fisheries accounted for 33% of economic output and 67% of employment in 1910.  Manufacturing and construction contributed only 23% to economic output, and over half of manufacturing production came from cottage industries employing less than five people.  Manufacturing consisted mainly of food products and textiles at 34% each, whereas heavy industry made up only 21% (21-23, 80).  In addition to surplus capital in search of higher profits overseas, Lenin stressed the acquisition of raw materials as a major reason for capitalists to acquire colonies.  Very little evidence exists to support that Japan acquired its colonies between 1894 and 1910 for raw materials.  Korea and Taiwan had no significant known mineral resources except for a small amount of iron ore in Korea, so the only substantial natural resources were agricultural products, mainly rice but also sugarcane in Taiwan.  Although Korea and Taiwan provided rice to Japan, especially in poor harvest years, only 18% of Japan's annual rice imports came from these two colonies from 1905 to 1910 (Duus 1984, 171).  After acquiring Taiwan as a colony in 1895, Japan encouraged the planting of sugarcane to supply domestic needs.  However, Taiwanese land devoted to sugarcane production from 1901 to 1910 was only 7% of the amount of land devoted to rice (Beasley 1987, 150), and Japan imposed a high tariff on sugar imports from countries other than Taiwan, so Japanese consumers suffered from higher prices.  The Kwantung Leased Territories had few natural resources, but they did help serve as a foothold to facilitate the development and extraction of Manchuria's natural resources (Ho 1984, 350).  Lenin's theory does not help explain Japan's imperialism from 1894 to 1910 due to the nonexistence of capital surpluses, the low level of economic activity with the colonies, the lack of dominance of the zaibatsu, and the low levels of the colonies' raw materials.  C. Schumpeter’s Theory  Schumpeter believed that imperialism represented the survival of older social structures, such as a warrior class, within a capitalist economy.  This theory seems to partially explain the attitudes of Japan's leaders toward imperialistic expansion.  Japan had a feudalistic social structure with a warrior class (samurai) until the downfall of the Shogunate in 1868 and the implementation of numerous reforms over the next five years under the new Meiji government.  Members of the former military aristocracy took leadership positions in the new government, and the military bent of some of these leaders became quickly evident, as they strongly pressed for military action in the early 1870s to conquer Korea.  A majority of the country's leaders decided to postpone this military action to concentrate on modernization and industrialization, but even the leaders who recommended not to go to war did not necessarily oppose the action in theory, only that the timing should wait until Japan became stronger industrially and militarily.  Although some authors contend that Japan's imperialistic spirit dated back to before the beginning of the start of the Tokugawa Period in 1600, they provide little evidence as to why such a militaristic attitude would remain entrenched in a people living in a country where peace reigned for about two and half centuries under the Tokugawa Shogunate (1600-1868).  Boulding and Gleason (1972, 241-242) argue that Japan's imperialistic expansion was a continuation from several centuries before: "Even before 1600, . . . colonies were established in areas of Southeast Asia, and in 1592 Korea was invaded in an extraordinary, but abortive, attempt to conquer China. . . . But the Meiji government, once isolationism had been abandoned, resumed the imperialistic practices of the earlier era."  Lockwood (1954, 7) argues that the coming of Westerners in the last half of the nineteenth century "revived and intensified memories of European ambitions and predatory rivalries dating back to the sixteenth century."  Although some leaders in the Meiji Era tried to revive memories of historical events for their own propaganda purposes, little evidence exists that such militaristic attitudes and memories of Western aggression continued in the Japanese people during a period of peace lasting over 200 years.  Schumpeter argued that capitalists have no economic incentives for imperialism, and Hobson also considered that imperialism is not profitable for a nation due its huge military and administrative costs.  The evidence in Japan's case supports Schumpeter and Hobson since the colonies did not provide profits for the country as a whole.  Lockwood (1954, 52) summarizes the effects of Japan's early imperialism:  But it is certain that colonial enterprise occupied a subordinate place in Japanese economic development during the first three decades of the twentieth century.  And it is likely that whatever contributions were made to Japan's national income and industrial development by political control over these areas were more than offset, even at the time, by the costs of the military outlays, developmental subsidies, and tariff preferences through which she acquired and developed her empire.  Duus (1984, 147) points out that business leaders during the period of Japan's early imperialistic expansion had much more interest in China, with a "vast population, size, and well-developed commercial economy" that "made its market larger, more penetrable, and more easily exploited than those of Taiwan or Korea."  Schumpeter's theory provides some insights into the reasons for Japan's imperialism from 1894 to 1910, but it fails to explain how Japan suddenly became an aggressive conqueror of foreign territories after over two centuries of self-imposed peaceful isolation.  D. Nationalism  The theory of nationalism provides the best explanations for Japan's imperialistic actions between 1894 and 1905.  The following points support nationalism as the best theory to understand Japan's wars and colonial acquisitions: (1) Japan's deep concerns for national security, (2) its emulation of the imperialistic behaviors of Western powers, and (3) Japanese national ideals and personal characteristics.  The United States forcibly opened Japan to the outside world in 1853.  Soon thereafter, Japan was pressured by the imperialist powers to sign "unequal treaties," which granted foreigners in Japan extraterritoriality in legal cases and which imposed on Japan low tariff rates for which the imperialist countries did not grant corresponding concessions in their rates.  The leaders of the Meiji government, formed in 1868 after the downfall of the Tokugawa Shogunate, considered national security and defense to be the top priority in order to prevent subjugation by the Western powers.  The nationalistic policy of fukoku kyōhei (rich country, strong military) emphasized Japan's goals to develop the country economically to catch up with the Western powers and to increase its military strength to ensure its existence as an independent country.  Japan fought the later wars against China and Russia in 1894-5 and 1904-5, respectively, to ensure that Korea would not be used by another imperialist power to threaten Japan's security.  Japan emulated the imperialistic behaviors of the Western powers.  From the beginning of the Meiji Period in 1868, Japan's leaders sought to make the country an industrial and military power on par with the Western imperialist powers.  When Japan emerged from its isolation and took steps to industrialize and modernize, the international environment was one of intense competition between powers that tried to maximize their political and economic positions relative to other powers and less developed countries.  Overseas colonies provided the imperialist powers with prestige and status, so Japan's leaders naturally celebrated when its empire expanded to include Taiwan, Korea, and the Kwantung Leased Territories.  The Western concept of Social Darwinism, with the ultimate domination of the world by the strongest nations, fit well with belief of many Japanese that they were the chosen people of Asia and a divinely favored race.  Yukichi Fukuzawa, one of Japan's educational leaders and founder of one of Japan's most influential newspapers, expressed Japan's early imperialistic desires in 1882, "We shall someday raise the national power of Japan so that not only shall we control the natives of China and India as the English do today, but we shall also possess in our hands the power to rebuke the English and to rule Asia ourselves" (Nester 1996, 63).  The Japanese people also had certain personal characteristics that supported the country's rapid economic growth and imperialistic expansion.  Allen (1981, 15) explains, "Throughout their history they have shown a gift for rapidly assimilating new ideas and practices, a boldness in executing large projects and, above all, a trained and frequently exercised capacity for organization."  4. Conclusion  The theories of Hobson and Lenin provide little insight into the reasons for Japan's imperialist expansion between 1894 and 1910 since the economic conditions they considered to be the causes for imperialism did not exist in Japan at the time.  Schumpeter's theory of imperialism has some relevance to Japan's case, since the leaders who promoted Japan's wars in the Meiji Period came from the former samurai class.  However, this theory does not fully explain Japan's imperialistic actions since the samurai did not fight for over two centuries during the self-imposed peaceful isolation of the Tokugawa Period.  Japan's concerns for national security, its emulation of Western powers in their imperialistic expansion, and Japanese national ideals supporting overseas expansion lead to the conclusion that nationalism provides the best explanation of Japan's imperialistic expansion in comparison to the other three theories of imperialism.  Although the theory of nationalism sheds the most light on Japan's imperialism from 1894 to 1905, this does not mean that Japan's aggression and colonial expansion represented the best course of action.  Kōtoku Shūsui, a Socialist leader in Japan, vividly described in 1901 imperialism's serious drawbacks (Iriye 1972, 75):  Imperialists in Japan and elsewhere are like drunken men, intoxicated by patriotism and militarism, which are nothing but expressions of their animal instincts.  They bleed people white with taxes, expand armaments, divert productive capital for unproductive ends, cause prices to rise, and invite excessive imports.  These are all for the sake of the state.  Government, education, commerce, and industry are sacrificed to patriotism, which is the root of militarism and imperialism.   Bibliography  Allen, G.C.  1981.  A Short Economic History of Modern Japan.  Fourth edition.  New York: St. Martin's Press.  Beasley, W.G. 1987.  Japanese Imperialism 1894-1945.  Oxford: Clarendon Press.  Boulding, Kenneth E. and Alan H. Gleason.  1972.  "War as an Investment: The Strange Case of Japan."  In Kenneth E. Boulding and Tapan Mukerjee, eds., Economic Imperialism: A Book of Readings, pp. 240-261.  Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.  Brown, Michael Barratt.  1974.  The Economics of Imperialism.  Harmondsworth: Penguin Books.  Cohen, Benjamin J.  1973.  The Question of Imperialism: The Political Economy of Dominance and Dependence.  New York: Basic Books.  Crawcour, E. Sydney.  1997.  "Industrialization and technological change, 1885-1920."  In Kozo Yamamura, ed., The Economic Emergence of Modern Japan, pp. 50-115.  Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.  Duus, Peter.  1984.  "Economic Dimensions of Meiji Imperialism: The Case of Korea, 1895-1910."  In Myers, Ramon H. and Mark R. Peattie, eds., The Japanese Colonial Empire, 1895-1945, pp. 128-171.  Princeton: Princeton University Press.  Gilpin, Robert.  1975.  U.S. Power and the Multinational Corporation: The Political Economy of Foreign Direct Investment.  New York: Basic Books.  Ho, Samuel Pao-San.  1984.  "Colonialism and Development: Korea, Taiwan, and Kwantung."  In Myers, Ramon H. and Mark R. Peattie, eds., The Japanese Colonial Empire, 1895-1945, pp. 347-398.  Princeton: Princeton University Press.  Hobson, J.A.  [1905] 1938.  Imperialism: A Study.  Reprint, with an introduction by Philip Siegelman, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.  Howard, M.C. and J.E. King.  2000.  "Whatever Happened to Imperialism?"  In Chilcote, Ronald H., The Political Economy of Imperialism: Critical Appraisals, pp. 19-40.  Lanham, Maryland: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers.  Iriye, Akira.  1972.  Pacific Estrangement: Japanese and American Expansion, 1897-1911.  Cambridge: Harvard University Press.  Lenin, V.I.  [1917] 1939.  Imperialism: The Highest Stage of Capitalism.  New York: International Publishers.  Lockwood, William W.  1954.  The Economic Development of Japan: Growth and Structural Change, 1868-1938.  Princeton: Princeton University Press.  Mommsen, Wolfgang J.  1980.  Theories of Imperialism.  Translated by P.S. Falla.  New York: Random House.  Nakamura, Takafusa.  [1971] 1983.  Economic Growth in Prewar Japan.  Translated by Robert A. Feldman.  New Haven: Yale University Press.  Nester, William R.  1996.  Power across the Pacific: A Diplomatic History of American Relations with Japan.  New York: New York University Press.  Nowell, Gregory P.  2000. "Hobson's Imperialism: Its Historical Validity and Contemporary Relevance."  In Chilcote, Ronald H., The Political Economy of Imperialism: Critical Appraisals, pp. 85-109.  Lanham, Maryland: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers.  Schumpeter, Joseph.  [1919] 1951.  "The Sociology of Imperialism."  In Imperialism and Social Classes, pp. 1-98.  New York: Meridian Books.    Home | Top | Other Papers and Essays | About the Author

The Best Historian In 2013/2014

This is to certify that I Tabaro Kaijage am the best historian of this year....

Friday, February 14, 2014

What is mercantalism?

Mercantilism is a national economic policy aimed at accumulating monetary reserves through a positive balance of trade , especially of finished goods . Mercantilism dominated Western European economic policy and discourse from the 16th to late-18th centuries. [ 1 ] Mercantilism was a cause of frequent European wars and also motivated colonial expansion. Mercantilist theory varied in sophistication from one writer to another and evolved over time. High tariffs , especially on manufactured goods, are an almost universal feature of mercantilist policy. Other policies have included: Building a network of overseas colonies; Forbidding colonies to trade with other nations; Monopolizing markets with staple ports ; Banning the export of gold and silver, even for payments; Forbidding trade to be carried in foreign ships; Export subsidies; Promoting manufacturing with research or direct subsidies; Limiting wages; Maximizing the use of domestic resources; Restricting domestic consumption with non-tariff barriers to trade . Mercantilism in its simplest form was bullionism , but mercantilist writers emphasized the circulation of money and rejected hoarding. Their emphasis on monetary metals accords with current ideas regarding the money supply, such as the stimulative effect of a growing money supply . Specie concerns have since been rendered moot by fiat money and floating exchange rates . In time, the heavy emphasis on money was supplanted by industrial policy , accompanied by a shift in focus from the capacity to carry on wars to promoting general prosperity. Mature neomercantilist theory recommends selective high tariffs for "infant" industries or to promote the mutual growth of countries through national industrial specialization [ citation needed ]. The term "mercantilism" was coined by its foremost critic Adam Smith . [ 2 ] While many nations practised it, one leading exemplar was France, the economically most important state, where king Louis XIV followed the guidance of Jean Baptiste Colbert , his controller general of finances (1662-83). They were determined that the state should rule in the economic realm as it did in the diplomatic, and that the interests of the state as identified by the king were superior to those of merchants and everyone else. The goal of economic policies was to build up the state, especially in an age of incessant warfare, and the state should look for ways to strengthen the economy and weaken foreign adversaries. [ 3 ] Influence Edit This section needs additional citations for verification . Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources . Unsourced material may be challenged and removed. (January 2010) Mercantilism was the dominant school of thought in Europe throughout the late Renaissance and early modern period (from the 15th to the 18th century). Mercantilism encouraged the many intra-European wars of the period and arguably fueled European expansion and imperialism – both in Europe and throughout the rest of the world – until the 19th century or early 20th century. Evidence of mercantilistic practices appear in early modern Venice , Genoa , and Pisa regarding control of the Mediterranean trade of bullion . However, as a codified school, mercantilism's real birth is marked by the empiricism of the Renaissance , which first began to quantify large-scale trade accurately. [ 4 ] England began the first large-scale and integrative approach to mercantilism during the Elizabethan Era (1558–1603). An early statement on national balance of trade appeared in Discourse of the Common Weal of this Realm of England , 1549: "We must always take heed that we buy no more from strangers than we sell them, for so should we impoverish ourselves and enrich them." [ 5 ] The period featured various but often disjointed efforts by the court of Queen Elizabeth to develop a naval and merchant fleet capable of challenging the Spanish stranglehold on trade and of expanding the growth of bullion at home. Queen Elizabeth promoted the Trade and Navigation Acts in Parliament and issued orders to her navy for the protection and promotion of English shipping. A systematic and coherent explanation of balance of trade was made public through Thomas Mun 's argument England's Treasure by Forraign Trade, or the Balance of our Forraign Trade is The Rule of Our Treasure. It was written in the 1620s and published in 1664. [ 6 ] These efforts organized national resources sufficiently in the defense of England against the far larger and more powerful Spanish Empire , and in turn paved the foundation for establishing a global empire in the 19th century. [ citation needed ]The authors noted most for establishing the English mercantilist system include Gerard de Malynes and Thomas Mun , who first articulated the Elizabethan System , which in turn was then developed further by Josiah Child . Numerous French authors helped cement French policy around mercantilism in the 17th century. This French mercantilism was best articulated by Jean-Baptiste Colbert (in office, 1665–1683), though policy liberalised greatly under Napoleon . In Europe, academic belief in mercantilism began to fade in the late 18th century, especially in Britain, in light of the arguments of Adam Smith and the classical economists . The repeal of the Corn Laws by Robert Peel symbolised the emergence of free trade as an alternative system. Neomercantilism is a 20th-century economic policy that uses the ideas and methods of neoclassical economics . The new mercantilism has different goals and focuses on more rapid economic growth based on advanced technology. It promotes such policies as substitution state taxing, subsidizing, spending, and general regulatory powers for tariffs and quotas, and protection through the formation of supranational trading blocs. [ 7 ] Theory Edit Most of the European economists who wrote between 1500 and 1750 are today generally considered mercantilists; this term was initially used solely by critics, such as Mirabeau and Smith, but was quickly adopted by historians. Originally the standard English term was "mercantile system." The word "mercantilism" was introduced into English from German in the early 19th century. The bulk of what is commonly called "mercantilist literature" appeared in the 1620s in Great Britain. [ 8 ] Smith saw English merchant Thomas Mun (1571–1641) as a major creator of the mercantile system, especially in his posthumously published Treasure by Foreign Trade (1664), which Smith considered the archetype or manifesto of the movement. [ 9 ] Perhaps the last major mercantilist work was James Steuart ’s Principles of Political Economy published in 1767. [ 8 ] "Mercantilist literature" also extended beyond England. Italy and France produced noted writers of mercantilist themes including Italy's Giovanni Botero (1544–1617) and Antonio Serra (1580–?); France's, Jean Bodin , Colbert and other physiocrats . Themes also existed in writers from the German historical school from List, as well as followers of the "American system" and British "free-trade imperialism," thus stretching the system into the 19th century. However, many British writers, including Mun and Misselden , were merchants, while many of the writers from other countries were public officials. Beyond mercantilism as a way of understanding the wealth and power of nations, Mun and Misselden are noted for their viewpoints on a wide range of economic matters. [ 10 ] Merchants in Venice The Austrian lawyer and scholar Philipp Wilhelm von Hornick , in his Austria Over All, If She Only Will of 1684, detailed a nine-point program of what he deemed effective national economy, which sums up the tenets of mercantilism comprehensively: [ 11 ] That every little bit of a country's soil be utilized for agriculture, mining or manufacturing. That all raw materials found in a country be used in domestic manufacture, since finished goods have a higher value than raw materials. That a large, working population be encouraged. That all export of gold and silver be prohibited and all domestic money be kept in circulation. That all imports of foreign goods be discouraged as much as possible. That where certain imports are indispensable they be obtained at first hand, in exchange for other domestic goods instead of gold and silver. That as much as possible, imports be confined to raw materials that can be finished [in the home country]. That opportunities be constantly sought for selling a country's surplus manufactures to foreigners, so far as necessary, for gold and silver. That no importation be allowed if such goods are sufficiently and suitably supplied at home. Other than Von Hornick, there were no mercantilist writers presenting an overarching scheme for the ideal economy, as Adam Smith would later do for classical economics. Rather, each mercantilist writer tended to focus on a single area of the economy. [ 12 ] Only later did non-mercantilist scholars integrate these "diverse" ideas into what they called mercantilism . Some scholars thus reject the idea of mercantilism completely, arguing that it gives "a false unity to disparate events". Smith saw the mercantile system as an enormous conspiracy by manufacturers and merchants against consumers, a view that has led some authors, especially Robert E. Ekelund and Robert D. Tollison to call mercantilism "a rent-seeking society". To a certain extent, mercantilist doctrine itself made a general theory of economics impossible. [ 13 ] Mercantilists viewed the economic system as a zero-sum game , in which any gain by one party required a loss by another. [ 14 ] Thus, any system of policies that benefited one group would by definition harm the other, and there was no possibility of economics being used to maximize the "commonwealth", or common good. [ 15 ] Mercantilists' writings were also generally created to rationalize particular practices rather than as investigations into the best policies. [ 16 ] Mercantilist domestic policy was more fragmented than its trade policy. While Adam Smith portrayed mercantilism as supportive of strict controls over the economy, many mercantilists disagreed. The early modern era was one of letters patent and government-imposed monopolies ; some mercantilists supported these, but others acknowledged the corruption and inefficiency of such systems. Many mercantilists also realized that the inevitable results of quotas and price ceilings were black markets . One notion mercantilists widely agreed upon was the need for economic oppression of the working population; laborers and farmers were to live at the "margins of subsistence ". The goal was to maximize production, with no concern for consumption . Extra money, free time, or education for the " lower classes " was seen to inevitably lead to vice and laziness, and would result in harm to the economy. [ 17 ] Infinite growth Edit The mercantilists saw a large population as a form of wealth which made possible the development of bigger markets and armies . The opposing doctrine of physiocracy predicted that mankind would outgrow its resources. The idea of mercantilism was to protect the markets, but it also helped to maintain the agriculture and those who were dependent upon it. Origins Edit Scholars debate over why mercantilism dominated economic ideology for 250 years. [ 18 ] One group, represented by Jacob Viner , sees mercantilism as simply a straightforward, common-sense system whose logical fallacies remained opaque to people at the time, as they simply lacked the required analytical tools. The second school, supported by scholars such as Robert B. Ekelund , portrays mercantilism not as a mistake, but rather as the best possible system for those who developed it. This school argues that rent-seeking merchants and governments developed and enforced mercantilist policies. Merchants benefited greatly from the enforced monopolies, bans on foreign competition, and poverty of the workers. Governments benefited from the high tariffs and payments from the merchants. Whereas later economic ideas were often developed by academics and philosophers, almost all mercantilist writers were merchants or government officials. [ 19 ] Monetarism offers a third explanation for mercantilism. European trade exported bullion to pay for goods from Asia, thus reducing the money supply and putting downward pressure on prices and economic activity. The evidence for this hypothesis is the lack of inflation in the British economy until the Revolutionary and Napoleonic wars when paper money came into vogue. A fourth explanation lies in the increasing professionalisation and technification of the wars of the era, which turned the maintenance of adequate reserve funds (in the prospect of war) into a more and more expensive and eventually competitive business. Mercantilism developed at a time of transition for the European economy. Isolated feudal estates were being replaced by centralized nation-states as the focus of power. Technological changes in shipping and the growth of urban centres led to a rapid increase in international trade. [ 20 ] Mercantilism focused on how this trade could best aid the states. Another important change was the introduction of double-entry bookkeeping and modern accounting. This accounting made extremely clear the inflow and outflow of trade, contributing to the close scrutiny given to the balance of trade. [ 21 ] Of course, the impact of the discovery of America cannot be ignored. [ citation needed ]New markets and new mines propelled foreign trade to previously inconceivable heights. The latter led to "the great upward movement in prices" and an increase in "the volume of merchant activity itself". [ 22 ] Prior to mercantilism, the most important economic work done in Europe was by the medieval scholastic theorists. The goal of these thinkers was to find an economic system compatible with Christian doctrines of piety and justice. They focused mainly on microeconomics and on local exchanges between individuals. Mercantilism was closely aligned with the other theories and ideas that began to replace the medieval worldview. This period saw the adoption of the very Machiavellian realpolitik and the primacy of the raison d'état in international relations . The mercantilist idea of all trade as a zero-sum game, in which each side was trying to best the other in a ruthless competition, was integrated into the works of Thomas Hobbes . The dark view of human nature also fit well with the Puritan view of the world, and some of the most stridently mercantilist legislation, such as the Navigation Ordinance of 1651, was enacted by the government of Oliver Cromwell . [ 23 ] Jean-Baptiste Colbert 's work in seventeenth century France came to exemplify classical mercantilism. In the English-speaking world its ideas were criticized by Adam Smith with the publication of The Wealth of Nations in 1776 and later David Ricardo with his explanation of comparative advantage . Mercantilism was rejected by Britain and France by the mid-19th century. The British Empire embraced free-trade and used its power as the financial centre of the world to promote the same. The Guyanese historian Walter Rodney describes mercantilism as the period of the world-wide development of European commerce, which began in the fifteenth century with the voyages of Portuguese and Spanish explorers to Africa, Asia and the New World. Policies Edit French finance minister and mercantilist Jean-Baptiste Colbert served for over 20 years. Mercantilist ideas were the dominant economic ideology of all of Europe in the early modern period, and most states embraced it to a certain degree. Mercantilism was centred in England and France, and it was in these states that mercantilist polices were most often enacted. France Edit Mercantilism arose in France in the early 16th century, soon after the monarchy had become the dominant force in French politics. In 1539, an important decree banned the importation of woolen goods from Spain and some parts of Flanders . The next year, a number of restrictions were imposed on the export of bullion. [ 24 ] Over the rest of the sixteenth century further protectionist measures were introduced. The height of French mercantilism is closely associated with Jean-Baptiste Colbert , finance minister for 22 years in the 17th century, to the extent that French mercantilism is sometimes called Colbertism . Under Colbert, the French government became deeply involved in the economy in order to increase exports. Protectionist policies were enacted that limited imports and favored exports. Industries were organized into guilds and monopolies, and production was regulated by the state through a series of over a thousand directives outlining how different products should be produced. [ 25 ] To encourage industry, foreign artisans and craftsmen were imported. Colbert also worked to decrease internal barriers to trade, reducing internal tariffs and building an extensive network of roads and canals. Colbert's policies were quite successful, and France's industrial output and economy grew considerably during this period, as France became the dominant European power. He was less successful in turning France into a major trading power, and Britain and the Netherlands remained supreme in this field. [ 25 ] Great Britain Edit In England, mercantilism reached its peak during the Long Parliament government (1640–1660). Mercantilist policies were also embraced throughout much of the Tudor and Stuart periods, with Robert Walpole being another major proponent. In Britain, government control over the domestic economy was far less extensive than on the Continent , limited by common law and the steadily increasing power of Parliament. [ 26 ] Government-controlled monopolies were common, especially before the English Civil War , but were often controversial. [ 27 ] The Anglo-Dutch Wars were fought between the English and the Dutch for control over the seas and trade routes. With respect to its colonies, British mercantilism meant that the government and the merchants became partners with the goal of increasing political power and private wealth, to the exclusion of other empires. The government protected its merchants – and kept others out – by trade barriers, regulations, and subsidies to domestic industries in order to maximize exports from and minimize imports to the realm. The government had to fight smuggling – which became a favorite American technique in the 18th century to circumvent the restrictions on trading with the French, Spanish or Dutch. The goal of mercantilism was to run trade surpluses, so that gold and silver would pour into London. The government took its share through duties and taxes, with the remainder going to merchants in Britain. The government spent much of its revenue on a superb Royal Navy, which not only protected the British colonies but threatened the colonies of the other empires, and sometimes seized them. Thus the British Navy captured New Amsterdam (New York) in 1664. The colonies were captive markets for British industry, and the goal was to enrich the mother country. [ 28 ] British mercantilist writers were themselves divided on whether domestic controls were necessary. British mercantilism thus mainly took the form of efforts to control trade. A wide array of regulations was put in place to encourage exports and discourage imports. Tariffs were placed on imports and bounties given for exports, and the export of some raw materials was banned completely. The Navigation Acts expelled foreign merchants from England's domestic trade. The nation aggressively sought colonies and once under British control, regulations were imposed that allowed the colony to only produce raw materials and to only trade with Britain. This led to friction with the inhabitants of these colonies, and mercantilist policies (such as forbidding trade with other empires and controls over smuggling) were a major irritant leading to the American Revolution . Over all, however, mercantilist policies had a positive impact on Britain helping turn it into the world's dominant trader, and an international superpower [ citation needed ]. One domestic policy that had a lasting impact was the conversion of "waste lands" to agricultural use. Mercantilists felt that to maximize a nation's power all land and resources had to be used to their utmost, and this era thus saw projects like the draining of The Fens . [ 29 ] Mercantilism helped create trade patterns such as the triangular trade in the North Atlantic, in which raw materials were imported to the metropolis and then processed and redistributed to other colonies. Other countries Edit The other nations of Europe also embraced mercantilism to varying degrees. The Netherlands, which had become the financial centre of Europe by being its most efficient trader, had little interest in seeing trade restricted and adopted few mercantilist policies. Mercantilism became prominent in Central Europe and Scandinavia after the Thirty Years' War (1618–1648), with Christina of Sweden , Jacob Kettler of Courland , Christian IV of Denmark being notable proponents. The Habsburg Holy Roman Emperors had long been interested in mercantilist policies, but the vast and decentralized nature of their empire made implementing such notions difficult. Some constituent states of the empire did embrace Mercantilism, most notably Prussia, which under Frederick the Great had perhaps the most rigidly controlled economy in Europe. During the economic collapse of the seventeenth century Spain had little coherent economic policy, but French mercantilist policies were imported by Philip V with some success. Russia under Peter I (Peter the Great) attempted to pursue mercantilism, but had little success because of Russia's lack of a large merchant class or an industrial base. Wars and imperialism Edit Mercantilism was economic warfare and was well suited to an era of military warfare. [ 30 ] Since the level of world trade was viewed as fixed, it followed that the only way to increase a nation's trade was to take it from another. A number of wars, most notably the Anglo-Dutch Wars and the Franco-Dutch Wars , can be linked directly to mercantilist theories. Most wars had other causes but they reinforced mercantilism by clearly defining the enemy, and justified damage to the enemy's economy. Mercantilism fueled the imperialism of this era, as many nations expended significant effort to build new colonies that would be sources of gold (as in Mexico) or sugar (as in the West Indies), as well as becoming exclusive markets. European power spread around the globe, often under the aegis of companies with government-guaranteed monopolies in certain defined geographical regions, such as the Dutch East India Company or the British Hudson's Bay Company (operating in present-day Canada). Criticisms Edit Much of Adam Smith's The Wealth of Nations is an attack on mercantilism. Adam Smith and David Hume were the founding fathers of anti-mercantilist thought. A number of scholars found important flaws with mercantilism long before Adam Smith developed an ideology that could fully replace it. Critics like Hume, Dudley North , and John Locke undermined much of mercantilism, and it steadily lost favor during the 18th century. In 1690, John Locke argued that prices vary in proportion to the quantity of money. Locke's Second Treatise also points towards the heart of the anti-mercantilist critique: that the wealth of the world is not fixed, but is created by human labor (represented embryonically by Locke's labor theory of value ). Mercantilists failed to understand the notions of absolute advantage and comparative advantage (although this idea was only fully fleshed out in 1817 by David Ricardo ) and the benefits of trade. [ 31 ] For instance, suppose Portugal was a more efficient producer of wine than England, yet in England cloth could be produced more efficiently than it could in Portugal. Thus if Portugal specialized in wine and England in cloth, both states would end up better off if they traded. This is an example of the reciprocal benefits of trade due to a comparative advantage . In modern economic theory, trade is not a zero-sum game of cutthroat competition because both sides can benefit. Hume famously noted the impossibility of the mercantilists' goal of a constant positive balance of trade [ citation needed ]. As bullion flowed into one country, the supply would increase and the value of bullion in that state would steadily decline relative to other goods. Conversely, in the state exporting bullion, its value would slowly rise. Eventually it would no longer be cost-effective to export goods from the high-price country to the low-price country, and the balance of trade would reverse itself. Mercantilists fundamentally misunderstood this, long arguing that an increase in the money supply simply meant that everyone gets richer. [ 32 ] The importance placed on bullion was also a central target, even if many mercantilists had themselves begun to de-emphasize the importance of gold and silver. Adam Smith noted at the core of the mercantile system was the "popular folly of confusing wealth with money," bullion was just the same as any other commodity, and there was no reason to give it special treatment. [ 8 ] More recently, scholars have discounted the accuracy of this critique. They believe Mun and Misselden were not making this mistake in the 1620s, and point to their followers Josiah Child and Charles Davenant , who, in 1699, wrote: "Gold and Silver are indeed the Measure of Trade, but that the Spring and Original of it, in all nations is the Natural or Artificial Product of the Country; that is to say, what this Land or what this Labour and Industry Produces." [ 33 ] The critique that mercantilism was a form of rent-seeking has also seen criticism, as scholars such Jacob Viner in the 1930s point out that merchant mercantilists such as Mun understood that they would not gain by higher prices for English wares abroad. [ 34 ] The first school to completely reject mercantilism was the physiocrats, who developed their theories in France. Their theories also had several important problems, and the replacement of mercantilism did not come until Adam Smith published The Wealth of Nations in 1776. This book outlines the basics of what is today known as classical economics . Smith spends a considerable portion of the book rebutting the arguments of the mercantilists, though often these are simplified or exaggerated versions of mercantilist thought. [ 19 ] Scholars are also divided over the cause of mercantilism's end. Those who believe the theory was simply an error hold that its replacement was inevitable as soon as Smith's more accurate ideas were unveiled. Those who feel that mercantilism was rent-seeking hold that it ended only when major power shifts occurred. In Britain, mercantilism faded as the Parliament gained the monarch's power to grant monopolies. While the wealthy capitalists who controlled the House of Commons benefited from these monopolies, Parliament found it difficult to implement them because of the high cost of group decision making . [ 35 ] Mercantilist regulations were steadily removed over the course of the Eighteenth Century in Britain, and during the 19th century the British government fully embraced free trade and Smith's laissez-faire economics. On the continent, the process was somewhat different. In France, economic control remained in the hands of the royal family and mercantilism continued until the French Revolution . In Germany mercantilism remained an important ideology in the 19th and early 20th centuries, when the historical school of economics was paramount. [ 36 ] Legacy Edit Adam Smith rejected the mercantilist focus on production, arguing that consumption was paramount to production. He added that mercantilism was popular among merchants because it was what is now called " rent seeking ". [ 37 ] However John Maynard Keynes argued that encouraging production was just as important as consumption, and he favoured the "new mercantilism". Keynes also noted that in the early modern period the focus on the bullion supplies was reasonable. In an era before paper money , an increase for bullion was one of the few ways to increase the money supply . Keynes said mercantilist policies generally improved both domestic and foreign investment. Domestic because the policies lowered the domestic rate of interest. And it increased investment by foreigners in the nation by tending to create a favorable balance of trade. [ 38 ] Keynes and other economists of the 20th century also realized the balance of payments is an important concern. Keynes also supported government intervention in the economy as necessity, as did mercantilism. [ 39 ] As of 2010 [update] , the word "mercantilism" remains a pejorative term, often used to attack various forms of protectionism . [ 40 ] The similarities between Keynesianism, and its successor ideas, with mercantilism have sometimes led critics to call them neo-mercantilism . Indeed, Paul Samuelson , writing within a Keynesian framework, defended mercantilism, writing: "With employment less than full and Net National Product suboptimal, all the debunked mercantilist arguments turn out to be valid." [ 41 ] Some other systems that do copy several mercantilist policies, such as Japan's economic system , are also sometimes called neo-mercantilist. [ 42 ] In an essay appearing in the 14 May 2007 issue of Newsweek , business columnist Robert J. Samuelson argued that China was pursuing an essentially mercantilist trade policy that threatened to undermine the post- World War II international economic structure. [ 43 ] Murray Rothbard , representing the Austrian School of economics, describes it this way: Mercantilism, which reached its height in the Europe of the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, was a system of statism which employed economic fallacy to build up a structure of imperial state power, as well as special subsidy and monopolistic privilege to individuals or groups favored by the state. Thus, mercantilism held exports should be encouraged by the government and imports discouraged. [ 44 ] In one area economists rejected Smith well before Keynes: in the use of data. Mercantilists, who were generally merchants or government officials, gathered vast amounts of trade data and used it extensively in their research and writing. William Petty , a strong mercantilist, is generally credited with being the first to use empirical analysis to study the economy. Smith rejected this, arguing that deductive reasoning from base principles was the proper method to discover economic truths. Today, many schools of economics accept that both methods are important. In specific instances, protectionist mercantilist policies also had an important and positive impact on the state that enacted them. Adam Smith himself, for instance, praised the Navigation Acts as they greatly expanded the British merchant fleet, and played a central role in turning Britain into the naval and economic superpower from the 18th Century onward. [ 45 ] Some economists thus feel that protecting infant industries , while causing short-term harm, can be beneficial in the long term. Nonetheless, the publication of The Wealth of Nations in 1776 had a profound impact on the end of the mercantilist era [ when? ]and the later adoption of free-market policy. By 1860, England removed the last vestiges of the mercantile era. Industrial regulations, monopolies and tariffs were withdrawn. [ citation needed ) by prof kaijage tabaro. Udsm. Kabone publisher

JIHAD WAR MEANS ? Read from here.....

TheJihadicmovements of the Western Sudan in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries can be seen as a sort of “grassroots” political movement turned revolutionary. Unlike the military conquests in Northern Africa, they were started by rural peoples to reform their own areas, thus they were revolutions, not conquests. Sheikh Usman dan Fodio’s SokotoJihadis the best known of the Western Africajihads, the most successful, and the first in the area to officially be declared as ajihad. [1]This uprising was caused by a confluence of factors. The Fulbe and Hausa peoples had long-standing ethnic and particularly religious hostilities, which drove a desire for political independence. Also, there is emergence of Sh. Usman himself, a credible Islamic leader to organize the resistance. Starting in the late seventeenth century, early efforts to establish Islamic states in Western Sudan provided some impetus toward later movements such as the SokotoJihad. However, while these revolutions were successful in establishing nominally Muslim governments and removing governments that had suppressed the religion, there was little effort to engage scholars (many of whom opposed them on religious grounds) or to universalize the movements intodaral-Islam, or a sense of community with other Islamic states. This is why they were not, strictly speaking,jihads, though they are sometimes referred to as such. [2]Jihadliterally means “struggle” and was already a part of established Islamic doctrine. Specifically, it means struggle to improve the self or society or to do the will of God, not necessarily for religious reasons. [3]Jihad al-sayf,orJihadof the sword, which I discuss here, is just one category of this. It means a struggle to defend the faith or theummah,the global Islamic community. It is obligatory that all Muslims struggle for righteousness. Unlike the earlier movements, the SokotoJihadwas framed in scholarly religious terms and great pains were taken to ensure doctrinal justification. [4] In the late eighteenth century, the area of Hausaland, in what is now Northern Nigeria, was in a state of crisis and social disarray. Ethnic divisions between the Fulbe people, who were mostly nomadic herdsman, and the ruling agrarian Hausa people persisted despite the groups having inhabited the same area for about five hundred years. Not only did the groups have different dominant occupations, their societies were structured very differently. They mostly spoke different languages and while both groups were largely Muslim, this was much truer of the Fulbe than the Hausa, whose kings still practiced traditional “native” religions. The non-Muslim Fulbe’s religion was quite different from the traditional religion of the Hausa and Fulbe Muslims saw Hausa Muslims as insufficiently pious. The population was growing, making it increasingly difficult for the Fulbe to move their herds. This increased tensions over land-control and limited the migratory Fulbe’s ability to escape conflict by moving on. Corruption was widespread in the Hausa government, with appointments being based on bribes, rather than merit. [5]It was into this situation that the Fulbe Sh. Usman dan Fadio was born in 1754, in Gobir, a state in Northern Hausaland. Sh. Usman dan Fodio began his political career around 1774 as an itinerant preacher, assailing the corruption of Islam through mixture with various local religions and the acceptance of many forbidden practices such as consumption of alcohol, women going unveiled and men taking more than four wives. He already was a scholar of some reputation, who had studied under al- Hajj Jibrilla ibn Umar, who taught that Muslims who do not follow Islamic law and do things like neglect the poor, live opulent lifestyles or freely mix men and women are, in fact, unbelievers. While Sh. Usman disagreed with his teacher on this, the commitment to restoring a pure Islam free from outside influence remained. He built a considerable following among the peasants of the area over the coming years, particularly, but not exclusively, in his own Fulbe ethnic group. Dan Fodio’s ancestors had migrated to Gobir in the first place because of oppression in Konni, but over time, the situation in Gobir also became increasingly oppressive. The various Hausa states were constantly at war with one another and sustained this practice through conscription. This forced Muslim men to fight in wars that were illegal under Islamic law. The Hausa had restricted Islamic religious practices such as prayer-calls and turbans and imprisoned some adherents for violating these laws. Also, as dan Fodio saw it, the government charged excessive taxes with no basis in the Koran. These taxes only applied to Muslim-dominated trades like herding and were designed to economically exploit the faithful. [6] Sh. Usman’s leadership ability soon earned him wider credibility and recognition. By 1789, he had amassed enough of a following that Bawa Jan Garzo, King of Gobir, viewed him as a political threat. He feared theJama’a, or autonomous Muslim community, was becoming too organized and this could make his own leadership redundant. This was, in fact, a quite reasonable concern. Dan Fodio attempted to meet with him in order to teach him about Islam and convert him to the faith, but this did not succeed. It only left the king assured he was dangerous. Jan Garzo attempted to have him killed by encouraging otherUlemas, or Muslim scholars, to conspire against him. However, dan Fodio was able to persuade them to support him, leaving the king with little support and forcing him to drop plans for assassination. In fact, Jan Garzo had inadvertantly validated Sh. Usman’s leadership and religious views. The Sheikh demanded the king free religious prisoners, allow the call to prayer, exempt Muslims from the draft and reform the discriminatory dress code and tax laws. The king agreed and a temporary peace was formed. Sh. Usman dan Fodio and Bawa Jan Garzo were now at least nominally allies. However, this was on dan Fodio’s terms. While the Sheikh did perform an intercessory prayer for him, much in the tradition of the older forms of court Islam, he did not actually become a member of the court. It does appear that he continued to visit Jan through the rest of his reign, but this is disputed. After this time, he moved to the town of Degel nearby. The first attempt to stop his rise to power had not only left him alive and free, but greatly increased his influence. [7] Sh. Usman dan Fodio was an important figure in the revolutions not just because of his political and scholarly talent, but because of his mystical experiences. His authority was based on a series of visions where he claimed to have been visited by the Prophet Mohammed as well as Abd al-Aqir al Jilani, founder of the mystical Qadiriyye order to which dan Fodio belonged. In 1794, he said they gave him “The Sword of Truth” and a mission to fight the enemies of Islam. He was reputed to be asharif, or descendant of the Prophet through his daughter, Fatima, and have the ability to perform miracles, though he may not have believed this himself. He never directly made any such claims in his writings, only oblique references, though this be modesty or uncertainty. [8]These factors combined elevated him to someone of far more significance than a mere scholar. He was not just a learned man, but a holy man with a divine mission. This is what ultimately gave him the authority to declarejihad. Dan Fadio’s increased profile only deepened conflict with Hausa leaders, but he continued to prevail. His successes with Bawa Jan Garzo legitimized perceptions that theJama’awere loyal to him rather than the king and were quickly becoming more powerful and more organized. Bunu Nafta, the new king, resented these offenses against his sovereignty. In 1800, he reinstituted many of the oppressive rules of his predecessors. He banned turbans for men and veils for women as well as proselytization of Islam, essentially trying to remove it from public visibility and keep the movement from growing. He captured and enslaved the Sheikh’s followers when possible, leading dan Fadio to order them to arm themselves for self-defense. Thus, the agreement on which the truce was based was now broken and in many ways things were even worse for theJama’athan before. Surprisingly though, this escalation in itself did not lead to open war. Nafta soon died, but the situation did not improve. In 1802, Nafta’s successor, Yunfa, attempted to personally kill Sh. Usman. Yunfa had an apparent seat built over the mouth of a well. This was a trap made in such a way that anyone who sat on it would fall to their death. However, Sh. Usman did not accept the seat. At this point, Yunfa drew a gun and fired, but a misfire spared his target while injuring Yunfa himself. [9]Much as had happened thirteen years earlier, the Sheikh not only survived the Hausu king’s attempt on his life, but benefited from it. In this case, Yunfa had delivered an apparent miracle. He had opened hostilities and turned public perception in dan Fodio’s favor. Hostilities further escalated the next year when Yunfa’s army once again enflamed religious hostilities. They were passing Gimabana, where Abdulsalami, a follower of Sh. Usman dan Fodio, lived. They demanded he offer a prayer blessing and send the town’s women out to cheer them, as was the local custom. Abdulsalami refused as this would have violatedpurdah,the Islamic principle of separation of the sexes and he saw it as an affront to the women’s dignity. Yunfa was enraged when he heard this and was determined to make an example of the town for their poor hospitality in order to prevent future insubordination. He sent his army back to capture the inhabitants, including the women, and bring them in for interrogation. To complete the insult to Islam, the women were stripped nearly naked and shackled for their march and their books, including theKoran,were burned. However, the party had to pass close by Degel. Sh. Usman raised a force and made the army release all Muslim captives. The humiliation of the prisoners is what caused full war. The protection and sanctity of womanhood was a very deeply held value in Islamic culture. This was the start of actual military conflict. [10]Once again, the Hausa leaders had escalated conflict with dan Fodio, only to lose. Now, not only did theJama’ahave more reason than ever to overthrow the Hausa government, they had an army and a general. War was inevitable at this point as the king could not let an attack on his army go unanswered. He raised a larger army and sent them to besiege Degel, forcing Sh. Usman to make ahijra, or flight.. Yunfa orderedHausaleaders to kill all theFulbepeople, who fled to Sh. Usman for protection, making his leadership official and giving him a large army. In 1804, he issued his declaration ofJihad. [11] The official motivation for theJihad, which is to say the one in the declaration, was the necessity of establishing acaliphateto rule over Muslims. Acaliphate, ruled by acaliph, is a form of government based on Islamic law. The declaration builds the case point by point that a kingdom ruled by a Muslim king is a Muslim kingdom and a kingdom ruled by a heathen is a heathen kingdom. When Muslims live in a heathen land they must perform ahijra. Apostates and backslidden Muslims who pay lip service to the religion but do not follow its precepts must be forced back into compliance. Since it is obligatory for all Muslims to promote righteousness and fight evil, all Muslims must force their leaders to convert to Islam or replace them, by force if necessary, or through flight to a Muslim state. This case is built on points of Islamic law where Sh. Usman believed there was consensus. These principles date back to the very founding of Islam, when Mohammed was both the religious and secular leader of the Muslim community. [12] The religious motivations do seem to be sincere. Beyond apostates, there was no effort to force non-believers to convert, though they did have to pay extra taxes much as Muslims had in earlier times. Several areas, in fact, did not convert but continued to coexist peacefully with the SokotoCaliphateafter the revolution was over in 1809. Rules of fair warfare based on Islamic Law were painstakingly followed, even though it meant giving up significant advantages in many cases. [13]However, it is important to remember that while Sh. Usman led theJihad,his followers may have had their own reasons for joining. Abdulsalami, one of the heroes of the Gimabana humiliation, got into a dispute over division of spoils and ultimately declared his own jihad against the SokotoCaliphate.Unlike most of the movement leaders, he was not a Fulbe. [14]This shows some degree of power motive and likely also ethnic conflict, but these were clearly mostly subordinate to religious motives. Sh. Usman, in fact, soon stepped down from his position ascaliphto return to a life of scholarship. [15] The declaration ofJihadwas widely circulated among the Muslim community and spread to neighboring states, such as Kano, Katsina and Daura, who had similar conflicts against theirHausarulers. The new capital of Sokoto was established, and the movement continued to expand until the Sokoto Caliphate covered most ofHausaland. [16]Obviously, there was no single cause for every participant and place. While there were long-standing conflicts over religious practice and its proper place in government and public life, these do not necessarily lead to open war, much less acaliphate. I can easily imagine a scenario where limited hostilities could have gone on indefinitely or where the Fulbe overthrew the Hausa, but just established a Muslim king rather than an Islamic governmental system. Therefore, the main causes of thejihadwere the emergence of a viable leader among theFulbeand an unusually confrontationalHausaking and the religious rationale that focused the conflict on global issues and expanded it far beyond its origins. Reference kaijage ,T. Et al. Historian society... Kabone publisher. Daressalaam

Ronaldo anatisha kweli soma hapa

Mwamuzi aliyechezesha mchezo wa ligi kuu ya Hispania kati ya Athetico Bilbao VS Real Madrid na kumtoa kwa kadi nyekundu mwanasoka bora wa dunia Cristiano Ronaldo wikiendi iliyopita amesimamishwa. Kamati ya marefa nchini Spain imemuadhibu refa Miguel Angel Ayza Gamez kwa kumsimamisha kwa mwenzi mzima na huku akiondolewa katika isti ya marefa watakaochezesha mechi za Real Madrid zilizobakia msimu huu. Refa huyo alitoa kadi nyekundu kwa Ronaldo ambayo ilionekana kuwa na utata mkubwa jambo lilopelekea malalmiko kutoka kwa klabu ya Real Madrid. Kutokana na kadi hiyo nyekundu ya moja kwa moja Ronaldo amefungiwa kucheza mechi tatu na atazikosa mechi tatu zijazo za timu yake dhidi ya Villarreal, Getafe na Elche. Hata hivyo kufungiwa kwa refa huyo aliyemsababishia kufungiwa huko kunaweza kuipa nguvu Real Madrid kukata rufaa dhidi ya kadi hiyo ya Ronaldo.

Je unamfahamu mchezaji mwenye kasi kuliko wote dunian..

East Africa Television (EATV) Je, unamfahamu mchezaji wa mpira wa miguu (Football) mwenye kasi zaidi duniani? Hii hapa ndiyo listi ya kumi bora, kuanzia namba 10 hadi anayeongoza namba 1. 10. Alex Sanchez - Barcelona (30.7 KPH = 18.7 MPH) 9. Arjen Robben - Bayern Munich (30.7 KPH = 19.1 MPH) 8. Frank Ribbery - Bayern Munich (30.7 KPH = 19.1 MPH) 7. Wayne Rooney - Manchester United (32.1 KPH = 19.9 MPH) 6. Lionell Messi - Barcelona (32.5 KPH = 20.2 MPH) 5. Theo Walcott - Arsenal (32.7 KPH = 20.3 MPH) 4. Cristiano Ronaldo - Real Madrid (33.6 KPH = 20.9 MPH) 3. Aaron Lennon - Tottenham Hotspur (33.8 KPH = 21 MPH) 2. Gareth Bale - Real Madrid (34.7 KPH = 21.6 MPH) 1. Antonio Valencia - Manchester United (35.2 KPH = 21.9 MPH) Yesterday at 3:00p

Monday, February 3, 2014

Nguvu za kiume hupungua ktk ndoa.. Soma sababu na tiba hapa....

KATIKA MAPENZI... !LINATOKEAJE?!!ELIMIKA KWA KUSOMA HAPA...! Kesiyawanaume kupungukiwa nguvu za kiume zimezidi kushika kasi, kiasi cha kufanya dawa za kuongeza nguvu hizo kuwa maarufu na zenye mahitaji makubwa katika jamii. Waganga wa kienyeji wamekuwa wakitumia dawa hizo kama tiba ya msingi ya kuwavutia wateja kwenye biashara zao. Hii inaonesha kuwa tatizo hili ni kubwa miongoni mwa wanaume wengi katika jamii yetu. Hata hivyo, utafiti unaonesha kwamba wengi kati ya wanaume waliowahi kutumia dawa za asili na zile za hospitali kuondokana na tatizo la upungufu wa nguvu za kiume hawakufanikiwa kupata tiba ya kudumu, matokeo yake wamegeuzwa kuwa watumwa wa kila wanapotaka kushiriki tendo lazima wabwie ‘kolezo’ la kuwasaidia kuamsha hisia zao. Kwa wanaume, ukosefu wa nguvu nijambolinalouma na kuondoa kabisa ujasiri. Wengi kati yao wako tayari kutumia pesa na uwezo wao wote kuhakikisha kuwa heshima ya tendo la ndoa ikuwa katika miliki yao daima. Lakini, watafiti wa masuala ya mapenzi nikiwemo mimi, tumegundua kuwa wengi kati ya hao wanaolalamika kupungukiwa nguvu za kiume, hawafahamu chanzo cha matatizo na namna wanavyoweza kuepukana na kasoro hizo. Ushahidi uliopatikana kwa waathirika wa tatizo hili, unaonesha kuwa wanaume wanapokabili upungufu wa nguvu za kiume huishia kujuta na kujilaumu wenyewe bila kutazama upande wa pili wa washirika wao, namaanisha wanawake. Zipo kesi za wanaume kujiua au kujinyofoa sehemu zao zasirikwa sababu ya kushindwa katika tendo la ndoa. Hali hii inatoa picha kwamba wanaume wengi hujitwika mzigo wa lawama wenyewe. DoktaBiancaP. Acevedo kutoka Chuo Kikuu chaCalifornia,Santa Barbaraanasema, wanawake huchangia kwa kiasi kikubwa tatizo la upungufu wa nguvu za kiume, jambo ambalo nami nalithibitisha kwa ushahidi wa kitaalamu ufuatao: 1: KAULI Miongoni mwa mambo ambayo mwanaume hataki kuyasikia yakitoka kwenye kinywa cha mwanamke ni kuambiwa HAWEZI TENDO LA NDOA. Mwanamke akimwambia mwanaume wakati au baada ya tendo kuwa hawezi, atakuwa amemsababishia tatizo kubwa la kisaikolojia ambalo litampelekea kupotea nguvu za kiume taratibu. Msaada unaohitajika kwa mwanamke anayekutana na mwanaume dhaifu kwenye tendo si kumwambia hawezi,balini kumtia moyo na kumsaidia kuweza. Wanawake wamewasababishia waume zao upungufu wa nguvu za kiume kwa kuwaambia maneno kama haya: “Yaani siku hizi sijui umekuwaje, yaani huwezi kazi kabisa!” 2 : UJUZI Wanawake wengi hasa waliopo kwenye ndoa, wanapuuza ujuzi kwenye tendo la ndoa. Hawajishughulishi kumsaidia mwanaume ‘kuwika’, si wabunifu na watundu, jambo hili humfanya mwanaume kushiriki tendo kwa kutegemea kupanda kwa hisia zake mwenyewe, hivyo anapokuwa amechoka au ana mawazo, hawezi kusisimka kwa vile hapati ushirikiano toka kwa mwenzake. Pamoja na wengi kutokuwa wajuzi, lakini wapo wengine ambao ni watundu mno kwenye sita kwa sita kiasi cha kumfanya mwanaume ajione kama mgeni wa mchezo huo. Kimtazamo, wanaume hupenda sana ushindi wakati wa ‘kazi’, lakini pale wanapogeuzwa ‘chekechea’ hupunguza uwezo wa kujiamini na kuruhusu hofu kuongezeka mawazoni mwao, hivyo kuwasababishia tatizo la upungufu wa nguvu za kiume. Inashauriwa kwamba, mwanamke anapokuwa na uelewa mkubwa wa masuala ya mapenzi hasa wakati wa tendo, asioneshe kiwango kikubwa kwa haraka bali amchukulie mwenzake kama mwanafunzi, asiwe na maneno kama: “Leo nakuja kukupa vitu adimu kuliko vya juzi, hakuna kulala kasi mtindo mmoja.” Kauli hizi huwaogopesha wanaume na kuwafanya wapungukiwe na nguvu. USAFI Mwanamke anapokuwa si msafi, huweza kumsababishia mwanaume matatizo ya upungufu wa nguvu za kiume. Sote tunafahamu umuhimu wa usafi wa mwili na kero za uchafu wakati wa tendo, hivyo ni wazi kuwa mwanamke akiwa mchafu atamfanya mwanaume apoteze msisimko na uwezo wa tendo la ndoa. Unadhifu wa mavazi na mwili ni muhimu sana katika mapenzi. GUBU Jambo lingine linaloweza kumsababishia mwanaume upungufu wa nguvu za kiume ni gubu au karaha za maneno ya uchokozi yasiyokuwa na kichwa wala miguu. Uchokonozi wa mambo, ugomvi, usaliti na hali ya kutokuwa na staha ni mambo yanayosababisha tatizo la upungufu wa nguvu za kiume. Mwanamke anapokuwa mwingi wa maneno ya kashfa, dharau na matusi huweza kumfanya mume amchukie na kutopenda kushiriki naye tendo. Uchunguzi unaonesha kwamba wanawake walioolewa wenye tabia hii, huwafanya waume zao wawe na msisimko wa kimapenzi kwa wanawake wa nje kuliko wake zao hao. USALITI Tabia ya usaliti kwa mwanamke ni chanzo kingine cha mwanaume kupata tatizo la upungufu wa nguvu za kiume. Mwanaume anapoona, kuhisi au kubaini kuwa anasalitiwa, huumia sana moyoni, maumivu ambayo hatimaye humfanya muhusika kuwa na mawazo mengi ambayo humuondolea hamu ya tendo.

Friday, January 31, 2014

UNAIFAHAAMU ASILI YA IMANI YAKO ? Soma hapa

KUTOKANA na familia ya Freeman Illuminati bloodline kuanzisha chama cha ‘Priory de Sion’kilichokuwa na lengo la kuingiza mafundisho machafu ndani ya imani ya kweli, dunia ililazimika kusubiri awamu nne za utawala wa serikali moja kabla ya kuunganisha dini na serikali na kuwa kitu kimoja. Kumbuka kwamba Mungu hutumia namba 1 hadi 12 ambapo namba 4 humaanisha ‘ukomavu na kuvunwa kwa mazao’ – rejea Marko 4: 26 kwa mbegu njema na Yakobo 1:14,15. Rais Nimrodi wa serikali ya awamu ya kwanza ndiye aliyepanda mbegu ya ‘tamaa’ ya kuanzisha serikali na dini moja itakayoitawala dunia nzima. ‘Tamaa’ ya rais Nimrodi ilitengeneza ‘mimba’ na kupelekea awamu ya pili ya serikali moja ya dunia chini ya Waamedi na Waajemi wakati huo Dario akiwa ndiye rais na ikulu ya serikali hiyo ikiwa katika eneo la Iran ya leo. Baada ya miongo kadhaa kupita, ‘Mimba’hiyo ilileta mtoto aliyepewa jina la ‘dhambi’ wakati wa awamu ya tatu ya serikali moja ya dunia iliyoitwa Uyunani chini ya rais Alexander mkuu aliyeweka ikulu yake huko Ugiriki. Historia inatuambia kwamba rais Alexander mkuu alikuwa katili na aliyefanikiwa kuua mamia kama sio maelfu ya watu duniani kote. Hatimaye mbegu ya ‘tamaa’ iliyopandwa na rais Nimrodi wa serikali ya awamu ya kwanza ilipotengeneza‘mimba’ na kuzaa mtoto ‘dhambi’, mtoto huyo alikomaa baada ya kufikisha umri wa utu uzima. Sasa hakuitwa ‘mtoto’ tena bali jina lake lilibadilika na kuitwa‘mauti’. Kumbuka kwamba kuna hatua nne za kukua na kukomaa kwa mbegu hadi wakati wa kuvunwa. Hivyo ndivyo ilivyokuwa wakati dunia yetu iliposhuhudia awamu nne za serikali moja ya dunia ambapo katika awamu ya nne palitokea mavuno yaliyoleta mazao ya muungano wa serikali na dini. Ulikuwa ni utawala wa serikali ya awamu ya nne (Roman empire) chini ya rais Constantine aliyeweka ikulu yake huko Roma ndipo imani ya kweli ilipokufa baada ya rais huyo kuanzisha dini iliyochanganya ukweli na uongo kwa kutumia kanuni ya‘Thesis x Antithesis = Synthesis. Imani ya kweli ilikuwa ni ‘Thesis’ wakati imani ya kipagani iliyoanzishwa na Nimrodi ilikuwa ni ‘Antithesis’. Imani hizi mbili zilichanganywa na rais Constantine na kuzaa kitu kinachoitwa ‘Synthesis’ yaani mchanganyiko wa ukweli na uongo. Hiyo ilikuwa ni baada ya miaka mingi kupita tangu rais Nimrodi alipotamani kuanzisha mfumo wa utawala uliunganisha serikali na dini na kuwa kitu kimoja. Hiyo ilikuwa ni awamu ya nne ya utawala wa serikali moja ya dunia. Naam! Dini iliyoanzishwa huko Roma wakati wa awamu ya nne ya utawala wa serikali moja ya dunia chini ya rais Constantine ilikuwa ni matokeo ya mbegu ya ‘tamaa’ ya rais Nimrodi ya kuanzisha mfumo wa serikali iliyoungana na dini katika utawala wa dunia nzima. Jambo hilo la kuunganisha serikali na dini pamoja na kuchanganya ukweli na uongo lilipigwa vita vikali na ‘waprotestant’ ambao hawakuwa tayari kuona ukweli wa neno la Mungu ukichanganywa na uongo. Hata hivyo ‘waprotestant’ hao hawakufanikiwa kutenganisha serikali na dini na ndipo wakamua kujitenga na dini iliyokuwa imeungana na serikali ili wapate kumuabudu Mungu katika roho na kweli. Ilipofika mwaka 1798 kulitokea badiliko katika serikali iliyoungana na dini baada ya rais na kiongozi wa dini kukamatwa na kuuawa huko ufaransa. Baada ya kifo cha rais na kiongozi wa dini wa serikali moja ya dunia, ilionekana kana kwamba ndio mwisho wa mfumo wa utawala uliounganisha serikali na dini. Lakini haukuwa mwisho kwa sababu liliundwa taifa moja katika mji wa Roma likiwa linaendeleza mfumo wa kuunganisha serikali na dini. Taifa hilo likapewa jina la Vatican. Ndioo! Vatican ni nchi inayotawalaiwa na Papa akiwa ndiye rais na kiongozi wa dini pia. Sasa jina la serikali hiyo likaitwa ‘Roman Catholic’ yaani ‘ulimwengu wa Kirumi’. Maana ya neno ‘catholic’ ni ‘universal’ au iliyoenea dunia nzima. Serikali hii imeenea dunia nzima kutokana na uwepo wa wawakilishi (mabalozi) wa taifa hilo duniani kote. Ukilinganisha na mataifa mengine katika eneo la mraba, inawezekana taifa hili ndilo dogo kuliko mataifa mengine duniani kote lakini ni taifa lenye nguvu kubwa kuliko mataifa yote – usishangae! Zimekuwepo juhudi za kuhakikisha kwamba dunia nzima inarudi kwenye mfumo wa utawala wa serikali na dini. Freemasons wamekuwa kwenye mipango ya muda mrefu latika kuhakikisha kwamba serikali moja ya dunia itakayounganisha dini na uchumi kwa pamoja inaundwa haraka iwezekanavyo. Serikali hiyo itakuwa imejengwa kwenye msingi uliowekwa na rais wa kwanza katika awamu ya kwanza ya utawala wa serikali moja ya dunia. Itakumbukwa kwamba rais Nimrodi alianzisha dini iliyoabudu miungu (sayari) 36 ambapo jumla ya miungu hao ilileta namba 666. ..... Safari ijayo tutaitazama namba 666 na uhusiano wake na Freemasons .... Endelea kuwa na NDGSHILATU BLOG mahala popote na wakati wowote ..... FREEMASONS NA HEKA HEKA ZA MWISHO WA DUNIA Naam! Disemba 21, 2012 imepita; Sayari yetu haikugongwa na kupasuka na Hatukuona mwisho wa dunia! Lakini ni nini kimetokea? Ilifanyika mikutano kadhaa katika pande nne za dunia. Moja ya mikutano hiyo ni ule uliofanyika Vatican siku 18 (6+6+6) kabla ya Disemba 21. Mkutano huo ulifanyika siku ya Disemba 3, 2012 ukiwahusisha wakuu wa kanisa Katoliki katika kile kinachojulikana kama ‘Pontifical Council for Justice and Peace’ ambapo kiongozi mkuu wa kanisa hilo Papa Benedict xvi ndiye aliyehutubia mkutano huo. Akihutubia makumi ya makadinali waliohudhuria kwenye mkutano huo Papa Benedict xvi alitoa wito wa kuundwa kwa serikali ya dunia (world government) itakayokuwa na mfumo mpya wa dunia (New world Order) kwa ajili ya kutatua matatizo ya kijamii na kiuchumi. Kiongozi huyo wa kanisa alikaririwa akisema kwamba kuna umuhimu wa kuundwa kile alichokiita:“construction of a world community, with a corresponding authority,” Kisha akaongeza kusema:“The proposed body (World Government) would not be a superpower, concentrated in the hands of a few, which would dominate all peoples, exploiting the weakest. Maneno hayo yanamaanisha kuundwa kwa chombo cha dunia kitakachokuwa na mamlaka ya umma ambacho hakitakuwa chini ya watu wachache watakaowanyonya wanyonge. Itakumbukwa kwamba mwaka 2010 Papa Benedict xvi alitoa wito wa kuundwa kwa ‘Central World Bank’ itakayoshughulikia maswala ya fedha duniani kote. Sasa msikilize muumini wa freemason na mfanyabiashara za kibenki bwana Paul Warburg akisema kwamba"We will have a world government whether you like it or not. The only question is whether that government will be achieved by conquest or consent."(maneno hayo aliyasema siku ya February 17, 1950, alipokuwa akilihutubia baraza la Seneti nchini Marekani).Warburg alimaanisha kwamba serikali ya dunia lazima ianzishwe, utake au usitake. Swali ni kama serikali hiyo itaanzishwa kwa makubaliano au kwa vita. Mwaka 1992, Dr. John Coleman aliandika kitabu kinachoitwa ‘Conspirators Hierarchy: The Story of the Committee of 300’. Katika kitabu hicho Dr. Coleman anaainisha watu wanaohusika na mchakato mzima wa kuundwa kwa serikali moja ya dunia au New World Order. Katika ukurasa wa 161 Dr. Coleman anaelezea malengo ya kamati ya watu 300 (mwenyekiti wake akiwa ni mkuu wa kanisa duniani) na kusema:"A One World Government and one-unit monetary system, under permanent non-elected hereditary oligarchists who self-select from among their numbers in the form of a feudal system as it was in the Middle Ages. In this One World entity, population will be limited by restrictions on the number of children per family, diseases, wars, famines, until 1 billion people who are useful to the ruling class, in areas which will be strictly and clearly defined, remain as the total world population. There will be no middle class, only rulers and the servants. All laws will be uniform under a legal system of world courts practicing the same unified code of laws, backed up by a One World Government police force and a One World unified military to enforce laws in all former countries where no national boundaries shall exist. The system will be on the basis of a welfare state; those who are obedient and subservient to the One World Government will be rewarded with the means to live; those who are rebellious will simply be starved to death or be declared outlaws, thus a target for anyone who wishes to kill them. Privately owned firearms or weapons of any kind will be prohibited." Kwa ufupi maneno hayo yanamaanisha kwamba kutakuwepo na serikali moja na mfumo mmoja wa kifedha ambapo kiongozi wa serikali hiyo atachaguliwa na watu 300 wanaounda kamati kuu ya serikali hiyo. Idadi ya watu duniani itapunguzwa kwa kuanzishwa sharia za kuwa na idadi maalumu ya watoto katika familia ambapo mbinu itakayotumika kutekeleza lengo hilo ni kusababisha magonjwa, vita, njaa hadi idadi ya watu ifikie bilioni moja duniani kote. Kutaanzishwa mfumo mmoja wa kijeshi utakaosimamia sharia katika nchi zote ambapo mipaka yote ya nchi zote itaondolewa. Wale watakaokuwa watiifu katika serikali hiyo watawezeshwa kuishi; wale watakaokuwa wapinzani na waasi wataanchwa wafe kwa njaa au kuhumiwa kama wavunja sharia. Haki ya kumiliki silaha za aina yoyote itaondolewa’. Itakumbukwa kwamba hivi karibuni watoto 20 na waalimu wao 6 waliuawa kwa kupigwa risasi katika shule moja huko Marekani. Baada ya tukio hilo serikali ya Marekani imeanza kupitia upya sheria za umiliki wa silaha kwa watu binafsi. Rais Barack Obama aliyeshinda uchaguzi ulioshirikisha vyama 6 nchini Marekani amekwisha saini mabadiliko kadhaa ya sheria. Rais Obama amesaini sheria inayoitwa TARP (Troubled Asset Relief Program) ambapo chini ya sheria hiyo mabenki yote (Wall street) pamoja na mabenki ya kigeni yanakuwa katika dhamana kwa serikali. Sheria nyingine ni H.R 347 (House Resolution) au“Federal Restricted Buildings and Grounds Improvement Act of 2011,”. Sheria hii inazuia maandamano ya kwenda kwenye majengo ya serikali ikiwa ni pamoja na zuio la kuendeleza majengo na ardhi. Wanaharakati wa haki za binadamu nchini Marekani (American Civil Liberties Union –ACLU)) wanaipinga vikali sheria hiyo kwamba inawagandamiza wanyonge. Sheria nyingine ni‘National Defense Authorization Act’ – NDAA. Sheria hii inampa nguvu na mamlaka rais wa Marekani kuamuru kukamatwa na kufungwa gerezani kwa mtu yeyote bila hata ya kufikishwa mahakamani na kufunguliwa mashitaka. Kama ulikuwa unafikiri kwamba rais Morsi Mohamed wa Muslim Brotherhood Misri amejipatia madaraka makubwa kupita kiasi, basi yupo pia rais wa Marekani chini ya NDAA! Najua wengi watanishangaa ninaposema kwamba uchaguzi wa rais Marekani ulishirikisha vyama 6 na sio viwili. Ili usiniulize maswali juu ya hilo, vyama hivyo ni: 1)Democratic –Baraka Obama; 2)Republican – Miti Romney; 3)Libertarian Party - Gary Johnson; 4) Green Party- Jill Stein; 5) Constitution Party - Virgil Goode; na 6) Justice Party - Rocky Anderson.Kwa nini vyama 6 – ni namba ya utawala wa freemason.Kwa nini vyama vingine havikusikika? Ni kwa sababu Illuminati ndio walioshikilia ‘media’ na wao ndio waamuzi wa nani atangazwe na nani hapana. Nini maana ya wito wa kuundwa kwa ‘world community’ pamoja na ‘Central World Bank’ kutoka kwa Papa Benedict xvi? Ni kutimizwa kwa unabii wa Ufunuo 13:17. Haitawezekana kuzuiwa kuuza na kununua kama hakuna chombo kinachosimamia uchumi na fedha. Chombo hicho ni ‘Central World Bank’ (CWB). Lakini pia CWB haitakuwa na nguvu za kusimamia shughuli za kifedha kama hakuna serikali nyuma yake. Serikali hiyo ni ‘World Community Authority’ au ‘World Government’ yaani serikali ya dunia. Wakati Papa Benedict xvi akitoa wito wa kuleta ‘haki na amani’ duniani, chuo kikuu cha Kiislamu (Sunn Al - Azhar University) kimetoa shukrani kwa Vatican kutokana na juhudi za kanisa Katoliki kwa kukemea vitendo vinavyoashiria uvunjifu wa amani duniani, kutetea imani za watu wote pamoja na kuziwezesha dini zote kutumia alama na nembo kama utambulisho wa dini husika. Akihojiwa na waandishi wa habari, Mahmoud Azab ambaye ni mshauri wa Sheikh anayesimamia kitengo cha mahusiano ya kidini (interfaith Dialogue) katika chuo kikuu cha Al-Azhar, aliwashukuru wote wanaotetea ukweli na heshima ya dini. Mahmoud Azab alikuwa akijibu hotuba iliyotolewa hapo kabla na msemaji wa Vatican Fr. Federico Lombardi. Kwa nini Mahmoud atoe shukrani kwa Papa kutokana na matumizi ya alama/nembo katika dini? Unaweza kuchunguza alama/nembo kwenye jengo la chuo kikuu cha Al-Azhar na jengo alipokaa Papa Benedict xvi akihutubia baraza la haki na amani Vatican. Unazikumbuka kanuni 3 wanazotumia freemasons kufanya kazi zao? Tafakari! Itakumbukwa kwamba baada ya kushambuliwa kwa ubalozi wa Marekani mjini Benghazi na kuuawa kwa aliyekuwa balozi wa Marekani nchini Libya kutokana na hasira za waumini wa kiislamu zilizotokana na kutolewa kwa sinema inayomkashifu SAW Mohammad (Innocence of Muslims), Fr. Federico Lombardialitoa matamko na kusema kwamba:“profound respect for the beliefs, texts, outstanding figures and symbols of the various religions is an essential precondition for the peaceful coexistence of peoples”akiwa anamaanisha kwamba ili pawepo na amani kwa watu, kunatakiwa pawepo na kuheshimu imani, maandiko pamoja na alama/nembo mbalimbali zinazotumiwa na dini kama utambulisho wao. Akielezea kwa nini pamekuwepo na mjadala kati ya Al-Azhar University na Vatican, Abdel Muti al-Bayoumi, mjumbe wa ‘Islamic Research Academy’ katika chuo kikuu cha Al-Azhar alisema kwamba mjadala huo hauhusiani na kauli ya Papa Benedict xvi aliyoitoa kwa kuwatetea Wakristo wa dhehebu la Christian Copts wa Misri ambao wamekuwa katika wakati mgumu kutokana na kushambuliwa kwa sababu ya imani yao. Alipoulizwa kutoa kauli juu ya mjadala kati ya pande hizo mbili, Mahamoud Azab alisema, ““I have nothing to say on the subject at this present time” akimaanisha kwamba hawezi kusema juu ya mjadala huo kwa wakati huu. Hata hivyo Azab alikemea vikali vitendo vinavyofanywa na baadhi ya waumini kwa kuchoma Biblia wakati wa maandamano yaliyofanyika kupinga sinema ya ‘Innocence of Muslims’.Aliwataka waislamu wote kuheshimu Torah, Injili na maandiko Matakatifu kwa sababu ndivyo alivyofanya mtume Mohammad SAW. Kwa nini pawepo na mfululizo wa mijadala kati ya Al-Azhar University na Vatican; serikali ya Iran na Vatican na hata serikali ya Saud Arabia na Vatican? Wiki jana nilielezea vyanzo vya baadhi ya makanisa. Sikuelezea historia ya kanisa la Roman Katoliki na lini lilianza.Lakini pia sikuelezea historia ya dini ya Kiislamu. Kwa uchache kanisa la Roman Catholic ni kanisa la Roma, kama linavyojulikana, kanisa la Roma.Roma ni mji mashuhuri uliopo Italia. Mji wa Roma una historia ndefu katika dunia na ni mji uliotabiriwa na Mungu pia. Dunia yetu imewahi kushuhudia ikitawaliwa na serikali moja katika awamu nne. Awamu ya kwanza ilikuwa ni serikali ya dunia iliyopewa jina la Babeli. Rais au mfalme wakwanza katika serikali hiyo alikuwa ni Nimrodi akifuatiwa na Nebukadneza pamoja na marais waliomfuata. Asili ya serikali hii ni mnara wa Babeli uliojengwa na mfalme wa kwanza wa Babeli, rais Nimrodi. Eneo la sasa yalipokuwa makao makuu ya serikali ya dunia awamu ya kwanza ni Iraqi. Awamu ya pili ya serikali ya dunia iliitwa Mede/Uajemi ambapo mmoja wa marais wa serikali hii aliitwa Dario.Eneo la sasa yalipokuwa makao makuu ya serikali hii ni Iran ya leo. Awamu ya tatu ya serikali ya dunia iliitwa serikali ya Uyunani au Greece government. Mmoja wa marais mashuhuri katika serikali hii alikuwa ni Alexander mkuu (Alexander the Great). Awamu ya nne ya serikali ya dunia iliitwa‘Roman Empire’ au himaya ya Roma. Mmoja wa marais wa serikali hii alikuwa ni Constantine. Serikali hii ndiyo iliyotawala kwa muda mrefu kuliko serikali zote zilizoitangulia. Wakati serikali hizo zinatawala dunia, dini ya kweli ilikuwa haijatikiswa hadi serikali ya Roma ilipoanza kutawala. Je, dini ya freemasons ilianza lini? Ukiondoa dini aliyoianzisha Mungu katika bustani ya Edeni, dini ya freemasons ndiyo dini iliyoanza siku nyingi kuliko dini nyingine.Dini hii ilianzishwa pia kwenye bustani ya Eden mwanzilishi wake akiwa ni Shetani. Alimtumia Kaini anayejulikana kwa freemasons wa leo kama ‘first freemason’ yaani mjenzi huru wa kwanza. Hatimaye rais Constantine kwa nusu aliamua kuachana na ibada za kipagani na kujiunga na Ukristo. Hii ilikuwa ni kutimizwa kwa andiko la 2 Wathesalonike 2:3,4 maana ulikuwa ni ukengeufu wa kanisa la mitume sehemu ya kwanza uliopelekea kuanzishwa kwa dini iliyochanganya ukweli na uongo. Kwa nini dini hii ilisubiri hadi awamu ya nne ya serikali ya dunia? Pengine nizungumzie kidogo maana ya namba nne kama inavyotumiwa na Mungu. Namba nne sio namba maalumu kwa freemasons lakini ni muhimu sana kwa Mungu. Namba nne inamaanisha kukomaa kwa mavuno na kuvunwa. Tazama hapa: “Akawaambia ufalme wa Mungu, mfano wake ni kama mtu aliyemwaga mbegu juu ya nchi…..Maana nchi huzaa yenyewe,kwanzajani, tena(pili)suke, kisha(tatu),ngano pevukatika suke. Hata(nne)matunda yakiivamara aupeleka mundu, kwa kuwa mavuno yamefika” Marko 4:26 –kwenye mabano ni ufafanuzi wa mwandishi. Hizo ni hatua nne kufika kuvunwa kwa mbegu njema. Vipi habari ya mbegu mbaya? “Lakini kila mmoja hujaribiwa(kwanza)kwatamaayake mwenyewe. Halafuile tamaa ikisha kuchukuamimba(pili),huzaa dhambi(tatu),na ile dhambi ikiisha kukomaa, huzaamauti(nne)”Yakobo 1:14,15. Unaweza pia kujua ni kwa nini waisraeli walitumia miaka 40 (4x10) kutoka Misri hadi Kanaani; kwa nini Yesu, Musa walifunga kwa siku 40 (4x10). Kumbuka kwamba namba 10 kwa Mungu inawakilisha ‘ukamilifu wa Mungu’ na namba 7 inawakilisha ‘utimilifu wa Mungu’.Kuna tofauti kati ya ‘ukamilifu’ – ‘perfection’ na ‘utimilifu’ – ‘fulness’.Kitu kinaweza kuwa ‘timilifu’ lakini kisiwe ‘kamilifu’ lakini kitu hakiwezi kuwa ‘kamilifu’ bila ya kuwa ‘timilifu’. Kwa mfano mapigo 7 ni utimilifu wa ghabu ya Mungu lakini ukamilifu wa hukumu yake utafikiwa wakati Shetani, dhambi na wadhambi watakapoangamizwa motoni. Mungu alitoa amri 10 kwa wanadamu ikimaanisha kwamba amri hizo zinawakilisha tabia ya Mungu ambayo ni ‘kamilifu’. Lakini pia tunasoma “….Wewe wakitia muhuri kipimo, umejaa hekima na‘ukamilifu’wa uzuri” kisha anaanza kutaja ni kwa namna gani alikuwa‘mkamilifu’wa uzuri akisema “1)Akiki, 2)Yakuti manjano, 3)Almasi, 4)zabarajadi, 5)shohamu, 6)Yaspi, 7)yakuti samawi, 8)zumaridi, 9)baharamani na 10)dhahabu. Lusifa alikuwa‘mkamilifu wa uzuri’ kutokana na kuvikwa aina10za madini ya thamani kubwa. Mungu ni‘mkamilifu’kutokana na kuwa na tabia inayoelezewa kwenye amri10katika Kutoka 20:4-17. Je wewe ni mkamilifu wa tabia kama ya Mungu kwa kuzitunza amri 10? Tafakari! FREEMASONS NA FAMILIA 13 ZA ILUMINATI NI chama cha Prieure de Sion (Priory de Sion) kilichoanzishwa na familia ya 11 ya Illuminati inayoitwa Freeman Illuminati bloodlines ndicho kilichosababisha kuanzishwa kwa ‘Uprotestant’ au ‘Upinzani’ ndani ya dini. Wakainuka mashujaa wengi waliopinga mafundisho machafu yaliyoingizwa ndani ya imani ya kweli ili kutetea neno la Mungu litawale tofauti na mafundisho yaliyo maagizo ya wanadamu. Miongoni mwa mashujaa walioinuka kupingana na mafundisho ya chama cha Prieure de Sion alikuwa Martin Luther. Kumbuka kwamba wapinzani ‘Protestants’hawa walikuwa wanapinga mafundisho wakiwa ndani ya mifumo ya dini zao. Hata hivyo hawakufanikiwa kuleta matokeo mazuri ya upinzani wao na hivyo wakaamua kutoka na kujitenga na dini wakiwa na baadhi ya mafundisho machafu waliyoyarithi kutoka kwenye mifumo potofu ya kidini. Wakiwa wamejitenga, sasa waliamua kufanya ‘matengenezo’ kwa lengo la kuondoa mafundisho machafu na kubaki na mafundisho safi kama ilivyoagizwa na Mungu. Hivyo jina lao wakaitwa‘Reformers’ au ‘Wanamatengenezo’ badala ya ‘Protestants’ au ‘wapinzani’.‘Waprotestants’ wa awali walijua maana ya kanisa na ndio maana hawakuona shida kujitenga na mifumo iliyokuwa inadhaniwa kuwa ndiyo kanisa.Lakini je, nani aliyeanzisha ‘Uprotestant’na ‘matengenezo’? Ellen White anasema:“Christ was aprotestant...TheReformersdate back to Christ and the apostles. They came out and separated themselves from a religion of forms and ceremonies.Lutherand his followers did not invent the reformed religion. They simply accepted it as presented by Christ and the apostles." E.G. White, Review and Herald, vol. 2, 48, col. 2.Hapo anamaanisha kwamba ‘Kristo (Yesu) alikuwa ni Mprotestant….wanamatengenezo waliiga kutoka kwa Kristo na mitume. Walijitenga na dini ya desturi na sherehe. Luther na wafuasi wake hawakuanzisha dini ya matengenezo. Waliikubali kama ilivyoonyeshwa na Kristo na mitume’ [rejea: R&H, Vol. 2, 48, col.2]. Ni kwa namna gani Kristo alijitenga? E. White anaendelea kusema:“Pharisees and Sadducees were alike silenced.Jesus summoned His disciples, and prepared to leave the temple, not as one defeated and forced from the presence of his adversaries, but as one whose work was accomplished. He retired a victor from the contest”. {DA 620.2} ‘Mafarisayo na masadukayo walinyamazishwa. Yesu aliwakusanya wanafunzi wake, na akawaandaa kuliacha hekalu, sio kama aliyeshindwa na kulazimishwa kuondoka kwa maadui zake, bali kama ambaye kazi yake ilikuwa imekamilika. Alikuwa ni mshindi katika mashindano”. {DA 620.2} Biblia inasema kwamba Yesu alijitahidi kupingana na mafarisayo na masadukayo akiwa ndani ya mfumo wa dini ya kiyahudi na sasa alikuwa amefikia mwisho wa upinzani wake na akaamua kujitenga moja kwa moja na mfumo wa dini hiyo ili awafundishe vizuri wanafunzi wake ambao walikuwa tayari kukubali mafundisho safi. E.G. White anasema:" Hitherto He had called the temple His Father's house; but now, as the Son of God should pass out from those walls, God's presence would be withdrawn forever from the temple built to His glory. Henceforth its ceremonies would be meaningless, its services a mockery. {DA 620.4}Hatimaye Yesu na wanafunzi wake walijitenga na hekalu lililokuwa mpendwa wao. Lakini kwa sababu viongozi wa hekalu walikataa kufuata mafundisho ya neno la Mungu peke yake, Mwana wa Mungu hakuona sababu ya kuendelea kubaki ndani ya hekalu ingawa “Alikuwa akiliita hekalu kuwa ni nyumba ya Baba yake; lakini sasa, kama Mwana wa Mungu ambavyo akipita kutoka katika kuta hizo, uwepo wa Mungu ungeondolewa milele usionekane ndani ya hekalu lililojengwa kwa utukufu Wake. Hivyo sherehe zilizofanyika ndani ya hekalu hazikuwa na maana, huduma zake zikawa dhihaka”. {DA 620.4}. Hivyo ndivyo alivyofanya Martin Luther na wafuasi wake. Baada ya kifo cha Martin Luther, wafuasi wake waliendelea katika kufanya matengenezo. Hata hivyo kwa sababu freemasons hawakati tamaa, matengenezo yalikoma na kuanza kurudi nyuma taratibu ambapo leo hii wale wanaoitwa ‘Walutheri’ wameungana tena na mfumo ambao mwanzilishi wao, Martin Luther, aliuiita ‘mfumo mchafu’. Wakati matengenezo yanaendelea, ulikuwa ni wakati wa kutimizwa kwa unabii wa siku 1260 sawa na miaka 1260 kama ilivyotabiriwa na nabii Yohana. Wakati huo kulianzishwa matengenezo mengi na kupelekea kuanzishwa kwa mifumo mingine ya makanisa. Baadhi ya makanisa yaliyoanzishwa yalikuwa haya: Anglican: Lilianzishwa huko England na mfalme wa Uingereza ili kupinga kanisa la Roma. Kiongozi mkuu wa kanisa hilo ni Malkia wa Uingereza. Hata hivyo wachunguzi wa dini ya freemasons wanasema kwamba familia ya Malkia ni familia mojawapo kati ya familia 13 za waumini wa Freemasons. Presbyterian: Mwanzilishi ni John Calvin mwaka 1509 – 1564 na John Knox 1505 – 1572. Kanisa hili lilijitenga na Roma likiwa na motto “Chunguza maandiko” maana liliona kwamba kanisa la Roma linakwenda kinyume na maandiko. Hata hivyo wafuasi wa John Calvin na John Knox wameshindwa kufikia malengo ya kuyachunguza maandiko na kufuata kile asemacho Mungu na badala yake wamekubali kurudi walikotoka! MENNONITE:Lilizaliwa rasmi mwaka 1525 – 1530 na Conrad Grebel na wenzake akiwemo Zwingli Ulrich aliyetofautiana na Martin Luther juu ya somo la pasaka. Hawa walikataa ubatizo wa Roma wa kunyunyizia maji na jina jingine wanaitwa “Meno Knights” majina ambayo yanafanana na vikundi vya Freemason kama vile “The knights of Eulogia”(Skull and Bones), “The knights of Malta”. Ingawa lengo la Zwingli Ulrich lilikuwa zuri, baada ya kifo chake wafuasi wake walikubali kuingiliwa na freemasons na hivyo kushindwa kufikia lengo lililokusudiwa. LUTHERAN: Mwanzilishi ni Martin Luther mwaka 1517. Alikuwa ni Mjerumani aliyesomea ukasisi wa kanisa la Roma na mwaka 1511 akapata Phd katika chuo kikuu cha Wattenberg. Alipingana na kanisa lake la Roma na kuandika sababu 95 zinazopinga mafundisho ya Roma ndipo akajitenga na Roma na hivyo wafuasi wake wakaendelea kutumia jina la Lutheran, yaani wafuasi wa Luther. Wafuasi wa Luther hawakuendelea mbele na sasa wamerudi kwenye makosa aliyokuwa akiyapinga Luther. Je, Lutheran wa leo wanafuata kweli nyayo za Martin Luther? Au wametekwa kwa matumizi ya njama ya “Following Gurus”yaani kufuata kila wasemacho viongozi? Tafakari! Moravian: Mwanzilishi ni John Huss aliyezaliwa mwaka 1366 na kuchomwa moto na papa hadi kufa mwaka 1416 baada ya kulipinga kanisa la Roma. Wafuasi wake hadi leo wanaitwa kanisa la Moravian. Kwa bahati mbaya wafuasi wa John Huss hawakuendelea kufanya matengezo ili kusonga mbele zaidi ya Huss na kibaya zaidi ni kwamba wanarudi nyuma badala ya kusonga mbele. Leo Huss akifufuka atashangaa kuona jinsi wafuasi wake walivyoacha kanuni alizozianzisha. Je, wamoravian wa leo wako tayari kuchomwa moto kwa kutetea ukweli kama John Huss? Tafakari! Baptist: Ni kanisa lililoanzishwa na wafuasi wa Martin Luther ambao walijitenga na Lutheran mwaka 1600 huko Uholanzi na Uingereza baada ya kuona kwamba wafuasi wenzao wameacha kanuni alizoziweka Martin Luther. Hata hivyo kanisa la Baptist la leo haliendeleza jitihada za Luther na sasa badala ya kusonga mbele linapiga ‘marktime’ likiwa limegeuka nyuma. Salvation Army (Jeshi la Wokovu): Mwanzilishi ni Booth mwaka 1878. Kanisa hili lilianzishwa na wafuasi wa freemasons kwa lengo la kuchafua matengenezo ya kweli. Kumbuka kwamba Shetani hutumia fursa inayotolewa na Mungu akiwa na lengo la kuwafanya watu washindwe kujua kipi ni cha kweli na kipi sio. Katika kila matengenezo ya kweli, pamekuwepo na matengenezo bandia. Marmon church:Mwanzilishi ni Joseph Smith (1805 – 1844). Kanisa hili linajulikana pia kama The church of Jesus Christ of later day saints. Kanisa la Mormon lilianzishwa na wafuasi wa freemason wakiwa na lengo la kuchafua matengenezo ya kweli. Mitt Romney ni muumini wa kanisa la Mormon. Methodist: Kiongozi Mwanzilishi ni John Wesley. Lilianzishwa na watu 17 wa familia moja mwaka 1738 likiwa na lengo la kupinga mafundisho ya freemasons. Kanisa hilo halijakamilisha lengo la matengenezo kutokana na ukweli kwamba wafuasi wake hawana mwamko aliokuwa nao John Wesley. Watch Tower: Mwanzilishi ni Charles T. Russel 1852 – 1916 na mwenzake J. Lutheford 1869 – 1942. Baba yake Charles T. Russel alikuwa ni mchungaji wa Prebyterian. Mnamo mwaka 1932 huko Marekani jina la kanisa hilo lilibadilishwa na kuitwa Mashahidi wa Yehova. Markus Mpangala ameelezea kwa kirefu chanzo cha dhehebu hili akiainisha kwamba waanzilishi walikuwa ni Freemasons kutoka kwenye familia ya Illuminati inayoitwa Russel illuminati bloodline ambayo nimeshaielezea kwenye makala zilizopita. Brethen Assemblies: Mwanzilishi ni ndg. Dabi 1800 – 1882 ambaye alikuwa ni muumini wa Anglican na akajitenga na kanisa hilo na kuanzisha kanisa lake. Dabi aliamua kujitenga na Anglican kutokana na kanisa hilo kutawaliwa na familia ya freemasons. Makanisa ya Kipentekoste au kilokole: Ni makanisa yaliyoanzishwa miaka ya hivi karibuni. Makanisa haya yalianzishwa huko Kansas City Marekani mwaka 1901kwa lengo la kupata nguvu ya kile kinachoaminiwa kuwa roho mtakatifu. Je, unajua uhusiano uliopo kati ya muziki wa‘rap’ au ‘kufoka’ na uvuvio wa kunena kwa lugha kutoka kwa kile kinachoaminiwa kuwa ni nguvu za roho mtakatifu wakati waumini wa kilokole wanapokuwa wakiomba? Kumbuka kwamba Muziki wa rap ulianzia huko Kansas City Marekani, mahali ambako makanisa ya kipentekoste yalianzishwa. Panapo majaaliwa, nitakuwa na makala ndefu kuhusu asili, lengo na nguvu inayoonekana kwa viongozi wa makanisa ya kilokole kama akina T.B Joshua wa SCOAN la huko Nigeria. Kwa wakati huu nasema,‘Soma Biblia na Tafakari’! Gospel terbenacle: Mwanzilishi ni Pastor A.B. Simpson mwaka 1881 akitokea Presybiterian. Christian Churches: Mwanzilishi ni Thomas Chapel mwaka 1807 akitokea Presybiterian. Seventh –Day Advetist Church:Mwaka 1844 baada ya kutokurejea kwa Yesu duniani kama ilivyohubiriwa na muhubiri mashuhuri aitwaye William Miller, watu wengi walivunjika moyo isipokuwa watu 50 tu ndio walioendelea kujifunza Biblia miongoni mwao akiwa ni Ellen G. White. Watu hao waliendelea kuchunguza makosa yaliyofanywa na William Miller maana wao pia waliamini juu ya marejeo ya Yesu tarehe 22/10/1844. Hatimaye mwaka 1863 kanisa hilo likapewa jina la Seventh –Day Adventists Church huku likiwa na motto au kauli mbiu ya “Amri za Mungu na imani ya Yesu na Ujumbe wa malaika watatu” na baadaye kanisa hilo likawa chini yaraiswa General Conference ya SDA makao makuu yake yakiwa huko Marekani. Rais huyo ndiye kiongozi (kichwa) mkuu wa kanisa hilo duniani na huchaguliwa kila baada ya miaka mitano. Wakati viongozi wa kanisa walipokutana ili kujadili mambo ya kanisa, palikuwa na ‘Mwenyekiti’(Chairman of General Conference) ambaye aliongoza kikao hadi mwisho. Baada ya kikao kumalizika, mwenyekiti huyo alimaliza muda na kazi yake. Hata hivyo kulitokea mabadiliko kutokamwenyekitiwa baraza kuu hadi naraiswa kanisa ulimwenguni. Kila baada ya miaka mitano hufanyika uchaguzi wa kumpataraiswa kanisa hilo. Tofauti na makanisa mengine, kanisa hili linaabudu siku ya Jumamosi wakati makanisa mengine yanaabudu siku ya jumapili. Sasa hivi kuna makanisa mengi ya SDA ambayo yametoka ndani ya kanisa la ‘General conference of Seventh-Day Adventists’(GCSDA) kwa madai kwamba kanisa hilo limeingiliwa na freemasons. Wengi wa waumini wa SDA waliojitenga na GCSDA wanasema kwamba walikuwa wakipinga‘protest’ mafundisho machafu huku wakiendelea kuwa ndani ya GCSDA lakini hawakuweza kuleta mabadiliko yoyote maana hali ilikuwa inazidi kuwa mbaya. Hatimaye waumini hao waliamua kufuata nyayo za akina Luther za kujitenga na sasa wanafanya ‘reformation’ au ‘matengenezo’ hatua kwa hatua maana walitoka na mafundisho machafu ambayo waliyapokea kama kweli wakiwa ndani ya GCSDA.Waumini hao wanadai kwamba walijitenga na GCSDA kwa sababu Je, madai hayo ni kweli? Tafakari! Msingi wa kanisa la SDA au ‘Wasabato’ kama inavyojulikana kwa wengi,kuabudu siku ya jumamosi, ni kile kilichoandikwa na Mungu wakati wa uumbaji, kwamba aliumba kwa siku 6 na siku ya 7 akastarehe, akaibariki na akapumzika kisha akawaambia waisraeli: “Ikumbuke siku yaSabatouitakase….” Kutoka 20:8. Kutokana na kazi ya chama cha Priory de Sion kwa kuingiza mafundisho machafu ndani ya imani safi, kulitokea utitiri wa makanisa mengi ambayo yanadai kupinga uchafu huo. Hata hivyo wengi wa waumini wa madhehebu hayo ama hawajui asili ya dhehebu lao au hawajui asili ya kile wanachokiabudu. Wengi wamefundishwa na waalimu wa dini na kuwaamini bila hata ya kutaka kuhakikisha kwa akili zao kile wanachofundhishwa. Mungu ametoa nafasi ya kufahamu ukweli kwa kila mmoja wetu bila ya kutegemea viongozi wa dini. Umewahi kufikiri kwamba kama ungekuwa unaishi duniani wewe peke yako, ungemtegemea nani? Tafakari! BOFYA “LIKE” HAPO CHINI ILI KUPATA HABARI ZETU..!!